anystyle 1.0.0

Sign up to get free protection for your applications and to get access to all the features.
Files changed (82) hide show
  1. checksums.yaml +7 -0
  2. data/HISTORY.md +78 -0
  3. data/LICENSE +27 -0
  4. data/README.md +103 -0
  5. data/lib/anystyle.rb +71 -0
  6. data/lib/anystyle/dictionary.rb +132 -0
  7. data/lib/anystyle/dictionary/gdbm.rb +52 -0
  8. data/lib/anystyle/dictionary/lmdb.rb +67 -0
  9. data/lib/anystyle/dictionary/marshal.rb +27 -0
  10. data/lib/anystyle/dictionary/redis.rb +55 -0
  11. data/lib/anystyle/document.rb +264 -0
  12. data/lib/anystyle/errors.rb +14 -0
  13. data/lib/anystyle/feature.rb +27 -0
  14. data/lib/anystyle/feature/affix.rb +43 -0
  15. data/lib/anystyle/feature/brackets.rb +32 -0
  16. data/lib/anystyle/feature/canonical.rb +13 -0
  17. data/lib/anystyle/feature/caps.rb +20 -0
  18. data/lib/anystyle/feature/category.rb +70 -0
  19. data/lib/anystyle/feature/dictionary.rb +16 -0
  20. data/lib/anystyle/feature/indent.rb +16 -0
  21. data/lib/anystyle/feature/keyword.rb +52 -0
  22. data/lib/anystyle/feature/line.rb +39 -0
  23. data/lib/anystyle/feature/locator.rb +18 -0
  24. data/lib/anystyle/feature/number.rb +39 -0
  25. data/lib/anystyle/feature/position.rb +28 -0
  26. data/lib/anystyle/feature/punctuation.rb +22 -0
  27. data/lib/anystyle/feature/quotes.rb +20 -0
  28. data/lib/anystyle/feature/ref.rb +21 -0
  29. data/lib/anystyle/feature/terminal.rb +19 -0
  30. data/lib/anystyle/feature/words.rb +74 -0
  31. data/lib/anystyle/finder.rb +94 -0
  32. data/lib/anystyle/format/bibtex.rb +63 -0
  33. data/lib/anystyle/format/csl.rb +28 -0
  34. data/lib/anystyle/normalizer.rb +65 -0
  35. data/lib/anystyle/normalizer/brackets.rb +13 -0
  36. data/lib/anystyle/normalizer/container.rb +13 -0
  37. data/lib/anystyle/normalizer/date.rb +109 -0
  38. data/lib/anystyle/normalizer/edition.rb +16 -0
  39. data/lib/anystyle/normalizer/journal.rb +14 -0
  40. data/lib/anystyle/normalizer/locale.rb +30 -0
  41. data/lib/anystyle/normalizer/location.rb +24 -0
  42. data/lib/anystyle/normalizer/locator.rb +22 -0
  43. data/lib/anystyle/normalizer/names.rb +88 -0
  44. data/lib/anystyle/normalizer/page.rb +29 -0
  45. data/lib/anystyle/normalizer/publisher.rb +18 -0
  46. data/lib/anystyle/normalizer/pubmed.rb +18 -0
  47. data/lib/anystyle/normalizer/punctuation.rb +23 -0
  48. data/lib/anystyle/normalizer/quotes.rb +14 -0
  49. data/lib/anystyle/normalizer/type.rb +54 -0
  50. data/lib/anystyle/normalizer/volume.rb +26 -0
  51. data/lib/anystyle/parser.rb +199 -0
  52. data/lib/anystyle/support.rb +4 -0
  53. data/lib/anystyle/support/finder.mod +3234 -0
  54. data/lib/anystyle/support/finder.txt +75 -0
  55. data/lib/anystyle/support/parser.mod +15025 -0
  56. data/lib/anystyle/support/parser.txt +75 -0
  57. data/lib/anystyle/utils.rb +70 -0
  58. data/lib/anystyle/version.rb +3 -0
  59. data/res/finder/bb132pr2055.ttx +6803 -0
  60. data/res/finder/bb550sh8053.ttx +18660 -0
  61. data/res/finder/bb599nz4341.ttx +2957 -0
  62. data/res/finder/bb725rt6501.ttx +15276 -0
  63. data/res/finder/bc605xz1554.ttx +18815 -0
  64. data/res/finder/bd040gx5718.ttx +4271 -0
  65. data/res/finder/bd413nt2715.ttx +4956 -0
  66. data/res/finder/bd466fq0394.ttx +6100 -0
  67. data/res/finder/bf668vw2021.ttx +3578 -0
  68. data/res/finder/bg495cx0468.ttx +7267 -0
  69. data/res/finder/bg599vt3743.ttx +6752 -0
  70. data/res/finder/bg608dx2253.ttx +4094 -0
  71. data/res/finder/bh410qk3771.ttx +8785 -0
  72. data/res/finder/bh989ww6442.ttx +17204 -0
  73. data/res/finder/bj581pc8202.ttx +2719 -0
  74. data/res/parser/bad.xml +5199 -0
  75. data/res/parser/core.xml +7924 -0
  76. data/res/parser/gold.xml +2707 -0
  77. data/res/parser/good.xml +34281 -0
  78. data/res/parser/stanford-books.xml +2280 -0
  79. data/res/parser/stanford-diss.xml +726 -0
  80. data/res/parser/stanford-theses.xml +4684 -0
  81. data/res/parser/ugly.xml +33246 -0
  82. metadata +195 -0
@@ -0,0 +1,2957 @@
1
+ title | ESSAYS ON HORIZONTAL MERGERS AND ANTITRUST
2
+ blank |
3
+ |
4
+ |
5
+ |
6
+ text | A DISSERTATION
7
+ | SUBMITTED TO THE GRADUATE SCHOOL OF BUSINESS
8
+ | AND THE COMMITTEE ON GRADUATE STUDIES
9
+ | OF STANFORD UNIVERSITY
10
+ | IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS
11
+ | FOR THE DEGREE OF
12
+ | DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY
13
+ blank |
14
+ |
15
+ |
16
+ |
17
+ text | Przemyslaw Jeziorski
18
+ | June 2010
19
+ | © 2010 by Przemyslaw Jeziorski. All Rights Reserved.
20
+ | Re-distributed by Stanford University under license with the author.
21
+ blank |
22
+ |
23
+ |
24
+ text | This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-
25
+ | Noncommercial 3.0 United States License.
26
+ | http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc/3.0/us/
27
+ blank |
28
+ |
29
+ |
30
+ |
31
+ text | This dissertation is online at: http://purl.stanford.edu/bb599nz4341
32
+ blank |
33
+ |
34
+ |
35
+ |
36
+ meta | ii
37
+ text | I certify that I have read this dissertation and that, in my opinion, it is fully adequate
38
+ | in scope and quality as a dissertation for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy.
39
+ blank |
40
+ text | Peter Reiss, Primary Adviser
41
+ blank |
42
+ |
43
+ |
44
+ text | I certify that I have read this dissertation and that, in my opinion, it is fully adequate
45
+ | in scope and quality as a dissertation for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy.
46
+ blank |
47
+ text | Ali Yurukoglu
48
+ blank |
49
+ |
50
+ |
51
+ text | I certify that I have read this dissertation and that, in my opinion, it is fully adequate
52
+ | in scope and quality as a dissertation for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy.
53
+ blank |
54
+ text | C. Lanier Benkard
55
+ blank |
56
+ |
57
+ |
58
+ |
59
+ text | Approved for the Stanford University Committee on Graduate Studies.
60
+ | Patricia J. Gumport, Vice Provost Graduate Education
61
+ blank |
62
+ |
63
+ |
64
+ |
65
+ text | This signature page was generated electronically upon submission of this dissertation in
66
+ | electronic format. An original signed hard copy of the signature page is on file in
67
+ | University Archives.
68
+ blank |
69
+ |
70
+ |
71
+ |
72
+ meta | iii
73
+ title | Abstract
74
+ blank |
75
+ text | This thesis contributes to understanding the economics of mergers and acquisitions.
76
+ | It provides new empirical techniques to study these processes, based on structural,
77
+ | game theoretical models. In particular, it makes two main contributions. In Chapter
78
+ | 2, I study the issues arising when mergers take place in a two-sided market. In such
79
+ | markets, firms face two interrelated demand curves, which complicates the decision
80
+ | making process and makes standard merger models inapplicable. In Chapter 3, I
81
+ | provide a general framework to identify cost synergies from mergers without using
82
+ | cost data. The estimator is based on a dynamic model with endogenous mergers and
83
+ | product repositioning. Both chapters contain an abstract model that can be tailored
84
+ | to many markets, as well as a specific application to the merger wave in the U.S.
85
+ | radio industry.
86
+ blank |
87
+ |
88
+ |
89
+ |
90
+ meta | iv
91
+ title | Acknowledgments
92
+ blank |
93
+ text | I would like to thank my advisers Lanier Benkard and Peter Reiss for their guidance
94
+ | over the years, their patience and their constant feedback that helped me to consider-
95
+ | ably improve my work. Moreover, I would like to express my gratitude to numerous
96
+ | people I encountered who believed in me and supported me along my path to this
97
+ | degree. In particular, this thesis would have been impossible without my adviser
98
+ | Tomasz Szapiro at the Warsaw School of Economics. He motivated me and directly
99
+ | helped me to make my adventure in the United States possible. My interest in game
100
+ | theory and dynamic models was triggered by great conversations with my adviser
101
+ | Rabah Amir at the University of Arizona. I would like to thank him for his support
102
+ | and help while applying to Stanford GSB. Last but not least, I am grateful to all the
103
+ | community at Stanford University – professors, fellow students and casual friends –
104
+ | for creating a unique environment for my intellectual and personal development.
105
+ blank |
106
+ |
107
+ |
108
+ |
109
+ meta | v
110
+ title | Contents
111
+ blank |
112
+ text | Abstract iv
113
+ blank |
114
+ text | Acknowledgments v
115
+ blank |
116
+ text | 1 Introduction 1
117
+ blank |
118
+ text | 2 Mergers in two-sided markets: Case of U.S. radio industry 5
119
+ | 2.1 Preface . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
120
+ | 2.2 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
121
+ | 2.3 Radio as a two-sided market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
122
+ | 2.3.1 Industry setup . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
123
+ | 2.3.2 Listeners . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12
124
+ | 2.3.3 Advertisers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13
125
+ | 2.3.4 Radio station owners . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
126
+ | 2.4 Data description . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17
127
+ | 2.5 Estimation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
128
+ | 2.5.1 First stage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
129
+ | 2.5.2 Second stage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20
130
+ | 2.6 Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22
131
+ | 2.6.1 Listeners’ demand . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23
132
+ | 2.6.2 Advertisers’ demand . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23
133
+ | 2.6.3 Supply . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27
134
+ | 2.7 Counterfactual experiments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29
135
+ | 2.7.1 Impact of mergers on consumer surplus . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29
136
+ blank |
137
+ meta | vi
138
+ text | 2.7.2 Effects of product variety and market power . . . . . . . . . . 31
139
+ | 2.8 Robustness analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32
140
+ | 2.9 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33
141
+ blank |
142
+ text | 3 Estimation of cost synergies from mergers without cost data: Ap-
143
+ | plication to U.S. radio 35
144
+ | 3.1 Preface . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35
145
+ | 3.2 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36
146
+ | 3.3 Merger and repositioning framework . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38
147
+ | 3.3.1 Industry basics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38
148
+ | 3.3.2 Players’ actions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39
149
+ | 3.3.3 Payoffs and equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41
150
+ | 3.4 Estimation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42
151
+ | 3.4.1 Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42
152
+ | 3.4.2 Policy estimation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43
153
+ | 3.4.3 Minimum distance estimator . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46
154
+ | 3.5 Application . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48
155
+ | 3.5.1 Industry and data description . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48
156
+ | 3.5.2 Static profits . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50
157
+ | 3.5.3 Estimation details . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51
158
+ | 3.5.4 Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53
159
+ | 3.6 Conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56
160
+ blank |
161
+ text | A Additional material to Chapter 2 57
162
+ | A.1 Advertising demand: Micro foundations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57
163
+ | A.2 Numerical considerations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59
164
+ blank |
165
+ text | B Additional material to Chapter 3 61
166
+ | B.1 Estimation without acquisition prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61
167
+ | B.2 Radio acquisition and format switching algorithms . . . . . . . . . . . 62
168
+ | B.3 Policy function covariates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63
169
+ | B.4 First stage estimates: Dynamic model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65
170
+ blank |
171
+ |
172
+ meta | vii
173
+ text | Bibliography 68
174
+ blank |
175
+ |
176
+ |
177
+ |
178
+ meta | viii
179
+ title | List of Tables
180
+ blank |
181
+ text | 2.1 Simple example of advertising weights . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
182
+ | 2.2 Panel data descriptive statistics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
183
+ | 2.3 Estimates of mean and random effects of demand for radio program-
184
+ | ming. Stars indicate parameter significance when testing with 0.1, 0.05
185
+ | and 0.01 test sizes. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
186
+ | 2.4 Interaction terms between listeners’ demographics and taste for radio
187
+ | programming. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25
188
+ | 2.5 Product closeness matrices for chosen markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26
189
+ | 2.6 Slope of the inverse demand for ads θ2A , by market size . . . . . . . . 27
190
+ | 2.7 Estimated marginal cost (in dollars per minute of broadcasted advertis-
191
+ | ing) and profit margins (before subtracting the fixed cost) for a chosen
192
+ | set of markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28
193
+ | 2.8 Counterfactuals for all markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29
194
+ | 2.9 Counterfactuals for small markets (less than 500k people) . . . . . . . 30
195
+ | 2.10 Counterfactuals for large markets (more than 2,000k people) . . . . . 30
196
+ | 2.11 Slope of the inverse demand for ads θ2A , by market size . . . . . . . . 33
197
+ | 2.12 Robustness of counterfactuals . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33
198
+ blank |
199
+ text | 3.1 Change in the local ownership caps introduced by the 1996 Telecom Act. 49
200
+ | 3.2 Savings when two stations are owned by the same firm vs. operating
201
+ | separately . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55
202
+ | 3.3 Total cost savings created by mergers after 1996, compared to demand
203
+ | effects from Jeziorski (2010) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55
204
+ | 3.4 Format switching cost for chosen markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55
205
+ blank |
206
+ meta | ix
207
+ text | B.1 Covariates for the format switching strategy multinomial logic regression. 63
208
+ | B.2 Covariates for the purchase strategy logic regression. . . . . . . . . . 64
209
+ | B.3 Station purchase policy estimates - buyer/seller dummies . . . . . . . 65
210
+ | B.4 Station purchase policy estimates - other variables . . . . . . . . . . . 65
211
+ | B.5 Format switching policy estimates - format dynamics . . . . . . . . . 66
212
+ | B.6 Format switching policy estimates - current demographics . . . . . . . 66
213
+ | B.7 Format switching policy estimates - demographic dynamics . . . . . . 67
214
+ blank |
215
+ |
216
+ |
217
+ |
218
+ meta | x
219
+ title | List of Figures
220
+ blank |
221
+ text | 3.1 Dynamics of station acquisition and format switching . . . . . . . . . 50
222
+ blank |
223
+ |
224
+ |
225
+ |
226
+ meta | xi
227
+ | Chapter 1
228
+ blank |
229
+ title | Introduction
230
+ blank |
231
+ text | A horizontal merger occurs when two or more competing companies combine to jointly
232
+ | operate. Both the European Commission (2004) and the U.S. Department of Justice
233
+ | (1997) recognize that such mergers may lessen competition and thereby harm con-
234
+ | sumers. Therefore, in order to prevent anti-competitive conduct, both bodies employ
235
+ | a set of analytical tools that predict and analyze the consequences of mergers. The
236
+ | dominant paradigm from the 1950s and through the 1970s was the structure-conduct-
237
+ | performance approach (see Bain (1968)). It assumes that market power is directly
238
+ | related to market concentration, and proposes using concentration indexes (e.g. the
239
+ | Herfindahl-Hirschman Index) for merger enforcement. This approach however, does
240
+ | not explicitly explain the conduct of firms and ignores many important issues, for
241
+ | example product differentiation, and heterogeneity of consumers or cost synergies.
242
+ | In contrast, modern industrial organization has developed new techniques, based on
243
+ | game theory, that endogenize the behavior of companies and allow for more detailed
244
+ | and robust evaluation of mergers.
245
+ | Current analysis of horizontal mergers in markets with differentiated products is
246
+ | based on a static supply and demand approach (e.g. Nevo (2000)). It is usually
247
+ | done in two steps. In the first step, one estimates a flexible demand system (e.g.
248
+ | Deaton and Muellbauer (1980), Ackerberg and Rysman (2005), Berry (1994), Berry,
249
+ | Levinsohn, and Pakes (1995)) and supply system. The demand system is a function of
250
+ | product characteristics, prices and heterogeneous consumer preferences. The supply
251
+ blank |
252
+ |
253
+ meta | 1
254
+ | CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION 2
255
+ blank |
256
+ |
257
+ |
258
+ text | system is determined by the equilibrium behavior of firms that maximize their profits.
259
+ | In the second step, one exogenously imposes a hypothetical merger and solves for the
260
+ | post-merger equilibrium using the estimates from the first step. The new equilibrium
261
+ | provides predictions about post-merger prices and quantities that can be used to
262
+ | identify the short-run impact of the merger on consumer and producer surplus. This
263
+ | thesis provides two extensions to this framework. First, it develops a new supply and
264
+ | demand system that encompasses the merger analysis of two-sided markets. Second,
265
+ | it proposes a dynamic framework in which mergers and product repositioning are
266
+ | endogenous. It allows for long-run predictions, including evaluation of possible fixed
267
+ | cost synergies of mergers. These methods are applied to analyze the 1996-2006 merger
268
+ | wave in the U.S. radio industry.
269
+ | In the chapter 2 of this thesis, I focus on how mergers affect two-sided markets. In a
270
+ | two-sided market, firms provide services to two types of consumers and facilitate their
271
+ | interaction via a platform. This creates cross-consumer externalities; thus, the profits
272
+ | of a firm operating a platform depend on sales to both types of consumers. Examples
273
+ | of such markets include the following: radio, in which stations sell ads and provide
274
+ | programming to listeners; credit cards, in which firms connect merchants and credit
275
+ | card holders; operating systems, in which revenue comes from hardware buyers and
276
+ | application developers. Antitrust analysis in these markets is complicated and it must
277
+ | take into account the market specific economic features (Armstrong (2006), Rochet
278
+ | and Tirole (2006), Evans (2002)). In particular, in the case of a merger, a firm has
279
+ | incentives to exercise market power on both sides of the market. These incentives are
280
+ | often conflicting. For example, in the radio market, stations sell advertising knowing
281
+ | it negatively impacts their listenership. On the one hand, a merged firm might sell
282
+ | more advertising in order to exercise market power on listeners. On the other hand, it
283
+ | might sell less advertising in order to exercise market power on advertisers. Chapter 2
284
+ | investigates this conflict by estimating a model of supply and demand for advertising
285
+ | and radio programming. Using this model, it performs counterfactual experiments
286
+ | that predict the post-merger advertising quantity supplied and the new division of
287
+ | surplus between listeners and advertisers. I find that mergers decrease the amount of
288
+ | advertising supplied, thereby increasing listener welfare by 1%. However, at the same
289
+ meta | CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION 3
290
+ blank |
291
+ |
292
+ |
293
+ text | time the decrease in ad supply raises prices and lowers advertiser welfare by $300m
294
+ | per year.
295
+ | A static analysis does not recognize that firms may adjust their product portfolio
296
+ | after a merger. In theory, mergers could increase or decrease product variety. On
297
+ | the one hand, they can increase the variety because a merged firm wants to avoid
298
+ | cannibalization. On the other hand, the firm might crowd products together to
299
+ | prevent entry. In the former case, if consumers prefer more variety, it is possible that
300
+ | repositioning could alleviate the negative effects of the merger (Berry and Waldfogel
301
+ | (2001), Sweeting (2008)). Chapter 2 provides a method to disaggregate the total
302
+ | impact of the merger on consumer surplus into changes in product variety and in
303
+ | supplied quantity. The same method can be used to predict whether extra variety
304
+ | could alleviate negative market power effects for a hypothetical merger. In the case
305
+ | of radio, extra variety alone leads to a 1.3% increase in listener welfare and decreases
306
+ | advertiser welfare by $147m per year. I find that product ownership consolidation
307
+ | and repositioning are followed by advertising quantity readjustments. I estimate that
308
+ | this effect alone leads to a 0.3% decrease in listener welfare (with the variety effect it
309
+ | sums to a 1% increase) and an additional $153m decrease in advertiser welfare (with
310
+ | the variety effect it totals $300m). While extra variety mitigates the negative effects
311
+ | of mergers on listeners, it increases the negative impact on advertisers.
312
+ | Chapter 3 deals with a dynamic merger analysis. The current empirical litera-
313
+ | ture on mergers and repositioning assumes that the market structure is exogenous
314
+ | (Nevo (2000), Pinkse and Slade (2004), Ivaldi and Verboven (2005)). This approach
315
+ | does not take into account dynamic processes like post-merger repositioning, follow-
316
+ | up mergers, and fixed cost synergies, that could potentially lower prices and provide
317
+ | consumers with other non-price benefits. Moreover, the assumption that mergers are
318
+ | exogenous may create a selection bias that results in overestimation of cost synergies
319
+ | (for example the estimator might pick up other unobserved components correlated
320
+ | with the propensity to merge). This thesis provides a new, dynamic framework in
321
+ | which decisions to merge and to reposition products are endogenous. Such an ap-
322
+ | proach provides consistent estimates of the long-run effects of mergers. In addition, it
323
+ | allows for the estimation of cost synergies without any data on cost. The framework
324
+ meta | CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION 4
325
+ blank |
326
+ |
327
+ |
328
+ text | is straightforward, easy to implement, and computationally tractable. Application to
329
+ | radio reveals that the 1996-2006 merger wave provided $2.5b per year of cost syn-
330
+ | ergies, which constitutes about 10% of total industry revenue. The scale of those
331
+ | efficiencies is a an order of magnitude higher than loss in surplus for advertisers.
332
+ meta | Chapter 2
333
+ blank |
334
+ title | Mergers in two-sided markets:
335
+ | Case of U.S. radio industry
336
+ blank |
337
+ title | 2.1 Preface
338
+ text | This chapter studies the consequences of mergers in two-sided markets by estimating a
339
+ | structural supply and demand model and performing counterfactual experiments. The
340
+ | analysis is performed on the example of a merger wave in U.S. radio; however, it is applicable
341
+ | to other two-sided markets like credit cards, trading platforms or computer games. There
342
+ | are two main contributions from this chapter. First, I identify the conflicting incentives of
343
+ | merged firms to exercise market power on both sides of the market (listeners and advertisers
344
+ | in the case of radio). Second, I disaggregate the effect of mergers on consumers into changes
345
+ | in product variety and changes in supplied ad quantity.
346
+ | The model is estimated using data on 13,000 radio stations from 1996 to 2006. I find that
347
+ | firms have moderate market power over listeners in all markets, extensive market power over
348
+ | advertisers in small markets and no market power over advertisers in large markets. Coun-
349
+ | terfactuals reveal that extra product variety created by post-merger repositioning increased
350
+ | listeners’ welfare by 1.3% and decreased advertisers’ welfare by about $160m per-year. How-
351
+ | ever, subsequent changes in supplied ad quantity decreased listener welfare by 0.4% (for a
352
+ | total impact of +0.9%) and advertiser welfare by an additional $140m (for a total impact
353
+ | of -$300m).
354
+ blank |
355
+ |
356
+ meta | 5
357
+ | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 6
358
+ blank |
359
+ |
360
+ |
361
+ title | 2.2 Introduction
362
+ text | Between 1996 and 2006, the U.S. radio industry experienced an unprecedented merger
363
+ | wave due to the 1996 Telecommucation Act, which raised ownership caps in local
364
+ | markets and abolished cross-market ownership restrictions. At the height of merger
365
+ | activity, about 30% of stations changed ownership each year and about 20% changed
366
+ | the format of broadcasted programming. In this paper, I use this merger wave to
367
+ | study the consequences of consolidation in two-sided markets. I make two main
368
+ | contributions. First, I identify conflicting incentives for stations to exercise market
369
+ | power on both sides of the market (in the case of radio, the two sides are advertisers
370
+ | and listeners). In particular, I separate the impact of consolidation on listener and
371
+ | advertiser surplus. Second, I decompose this impact into effects of changes on product
372
+ | variety and market power. As a result, I ask whether extra variety can mitigate the
373
+ | negative effects of a decrease in competition. Similar issues arise in other two-sided
374
+ | markets such as credit cards, newspapers or computer hardware. The framework
375
+ | proposed in this paper can be easily adjusted to analyze any of these industries.
376
+ | In two-sided markets, firms face two interrelated demand curves from two distinct
377
+ | types of consumers. These demands give merging firms conflicting incentives because
378
+ | exercising market power in one market lowers profits in the other market. In the case
379
+ | of radio, a company provides free programming to listeners but draws revenue from
380
+ | selling advertising that is priced on a per-listener basis. In the listener market, a
381
+ | merged firm would like to increase post-merger advertising because it captures some
382
+ | switching listeners. This advertising decreases the welfare of listeners and increases
383
+ | the welfare of advertisers. However, from the perspective of the advertising market,
384
+ | the merged firm would like to supply less advertising, which has the exact opposite
385
+ | impact on listener and advertiser welfare. The firm’s ultimate decision, which deter-
386
+ | mines the impact of consolidation on the welfare of both consumer groups, depends
387
+ | on the relative demand elasticities in both markets.
388
+ | In this paper, I separately estimate elasticities for both consumer groups using a
389
+ | structural model of the demand and supply of radio programming and advertising.
390
+ | Using those estimates, I perform counterfactual policy experiments that quantify the
391
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 7
392
+ blank |
393
+ |
394
+ |
395
+ text | impact of consolidation on listener and advertiser surplus. I find that market power
396
+ | on the listener side is similar across geographical markets. In contrast, the amount
397
+ | of market power on the advertiser side depends on market population. In particular,
398
+ | firms have a considerable control over advertising price in smaller markets; however,
399
+ | they are price takers in larger markets. Consequently, mergers result in firms lowering
400
+ | advertising quantity in small markets (less than 500 thousand people) by about 13%,
401
+ | which leads to a 6% per-listener increase in ad prices. Mergers increase listener
402
+ | surplus by 2.5% but at the same time decrease advertiser surplus by $235m per
403
+ | year. Conversely, in large markets (more than 2 million people) mergers lead to
404
+ | a 5.5% increase in total advertising minutes while per-listener price stays constant.
405
+ | This results in a 0.3% decrease in listener welfare as well as a slight decrease in
406
+ | advertiser welfare ($0.1m per year). The aggregate national impact of the merger
407
+ | wave amounted to a listener welfare gain of 1% and a $300m per year advertiser
408
+ | welfare loss. I conclude that listeners benefited and advertisers were disadvantaged
409
+ | by the 1996 Telecom Act.
410
+ | My work is related to several theoretical papers studying complexity of pricing
411
+ | strategies in two-sided markets. The closest studies related to this paper are: Arm-
412
+ | strong (2006), Rochet and Tirole (2006), Evans (2002) and Dukes (2004). The general
413
+ | conclusion in this literature is that using a standard supply and demand framework
414
+ | of single-sided markets might be not sufficient to capture the economics of two-sided
415
+ | markets. Additionally, there have been several empirical studies on this topic. For
416
+ | example Kaiser and Wright (2006), Argentesi and Filistrucchi (2007) and Chandra
417
+ | and Collard-Wexler (2009) develop empirical models that recognize the possibility of
418
+ | market power in both sides of the market. They use a form of the Hotelling model pro-
419
+ | posed by Armstrong (2006) to deal with product heterogeneity. I build on their work,
420
+ | incorporating recent advances in the literature on demand with differentiated prod-
421
+ | ucts. This allows me to incorporate richer consumer heterogeneity and substitution
422
+ | patterns (e.g. Berry, Levinsohn, and Pakes (1995), and Nevo (2000)) that are neces-
423
+ | sary to capture complicated consumer preferences for radio programing. Moreover, I
424
+ | supplement reduced form results on market power with out-of-sample counterfactuals
425
+ | that explicitly predict changes in supplied ad quantity and consumer welfare.
426
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 8
427
+ blank |
428
+ |
429
+ |
430
+ text | The second contribution of this paper is the decomposition of the total impact of
431
+ | mergers on consumer surplus into changes in product variety and effects of exercising
432
+ | extra market power from joint ownership. This exercise is motivated by the fact
433
+ | that in most cases consumers have preference for variety, so it is possible that extra
434
+ | variety created by mergers might mitigate the negative effects of extra market power.
435
+ | In order to verify the above claim, I quantify consumers’ value for extra variety and
436
+ | compare it to the loss in surplus coming from the extra market power. This approach
437
+ | relates to Kim, Allenby, and Rossi (2002), who compute the compensating variation
438
+ | for the changes of variety in tastes of yogurt and Brynjolfsson, Hu, and Smith (2003)
439
+ | who do the same for the variety of books offered in on-line bookstores. These papers
440
+ | assume away the fact that changes in variety will be followed by readjustments in
441
+ | equilibrium prices. In this paper, taking their analysis one step forward, I incorporate
442
+ | such strategic responses by performing counterfactual experiments.
443
+ | Berry and Waldfogel (2001) and Sweeting (2008) document that the post-1996
444
+ | merger wave resulted in an increase in product variety. I investigate their claim using
445
+ | a structural utility model and conclude that extra variety alone leads to a $1.3%
446
+ | increase in listener welfare. However, because product repositioning softened com-
447
+ | petition in the advertising market and caused some stations to switch to a “Dark“
448
+ | format 1 , advertiser welfare decreased by $147m per year. Additionally, I find that
449
+ | product ownership consolidation and repositioning are followed by advertising quan-
450
+ | tity readjustments. I estimate, that effect alone leads to a 0.3% decrease in listener
451
+ | welfare (with the variety effect it totals to the 1% increase) and an additional $153m
452
+ | decrease in advertiser welfare (with the variety effect it totals $300m). While ex-
453
+ | tra variety mitigates the negative effects of mergers on listeners, it strengthens the
454
+ | negative impact on advertisers.
455
+ | This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 outlines the questions investigated
456
+ | in the paper in a formal way and describes the structural model of the industry.
457
+ | Section 3 contains the description of the data. Estimation techniques used to identify
458
+ | the parameters of the model are described in Section 4. Results of the structural
459
+ meta | 1
460
+ text | When in “dark” format, the station holds the frequency so that other stations cannot use it.
461
+ | “Dark” stations typically do not broadcast or broadcast very little non-commercial programming.
462
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 9
463
+ blank |
464
+ |
465
+ |
466
+ text | estimation are presented in Section 5. Section 6 describes the results of counterfactual
467
+ | experiments. Robustness checks of different modeling assumptions are contained in
468
+ | Section 7. Section 8 provides the conclusion.
469
+ blank |
470
+ |
471
+ title | 2.3 Radio as a two-sided market
472
+ text | The radio industry is an example of a two-sided market (other examples include
473
+ | advertising platforms, credit cards or video games). Such markets are usually char-
474
+ | acterized by the existence of three types of agents: two types of consumers and
475
+ | a platform provider. What distinguishes this setup from a standard differentiated
476
+ | product oligopoly is that the platform provider is unable to set prices for each type of
477
+ | consumer separately. Instead, the demand curves are interrelated through a feedback
478
+ | loop in such a way that quantity sold to one consumer determines the market clearing
479
+ | price for the other consumer. In this subsection I argue that this feedback makes it
480
+ | complicated to determine whether the supplied quantities are strategic substitutes
481
+ | or complements (as defined in Bulow, Geanakoplos, and Klemperer (1985)). This
482
+ | creates important trade-offs in the case of a merger and affects the division of surplus
483
+ | between both types of consumers. The remainder of this subsection discusses this
484
+ | mechanism in detail using the example of radio; however, the discussion applies to
485
+ | the majority of other two-sided markets.
486
+ | In the case of radio there are three types of agents: radio stations, listeners,
487
+ | and advertisers. Radio stations provide free programming for listeners and draw
488
+ | revenue from selling advertising slots. First, consider the demand curve for radio
489
+ | programming. The listener market share of the radio station j is given by
490
+ blank |
491
+ text | rj = rj (q|s, d, θL ) (2.1)
492
+ blank |
493
+ text | where q is the vector of advertising quantities, s are observable and unobservable
494
+ | characteristics of all active stations, d are market covariates and θL are parameters
495
+ | of the listener demand. Since radio programming is free, there is no explicit price in
496
+ | this equation. However, because listeners have disutility for advertising, its effect is
497
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 10
498
+ blank |
499
+ |
500
+ text | ∂rj
501
+ | similar to price, i.e. ∂qj
502
+ | < 0.
503
+ | The market clearing price of an advertising slot in station j depends on the amount
504
+ | of advertising supplied and the number of listeners to station j. Therefore, the inverse
505
+ | demand curve for advertising slots is
506
+ blank |
507
+ text | pj = pj (q, rj (q)|s, d, θA ) (2.2)
508
+ blank |
509
+ text | where θA are parameters. Note that the advertising quantity affects the advertising
510
+ | price in two ways: directly through the first argument and indirectly through the
511
+ | listener demand feedback loop (the second argument).
512
+ | Suppose for now that each owner owns a single station and there is no marginal
513
+ | cost (I relax these assumptions later). In equilibrium, each radio station chooses their
514
+ | optimal ad quantity, keeping the quantities of the other stations fixed, i.e.
515
+ blank |
516
+ text | max pj (q, rj (q)|q−j )qj (2.3)
517
+ | qj
518
+ blank |
519
+ |
520
+ text | In contrast to a differentiated products oligopoly, the firm has just one control (ad
521
+ | quantity) that determines the equilibrium point on both demand curves simultane-
522
+ | ously. The first order conditions for profit maximization are given by
523
+ blank |
524
+ text | ∂pj ∂pj ∂rj
525
+ | qj + qj + pj = 0
526
+ | ∂qj ∂rj ∂qj
527
+ blank |
528
+ text | The important fact is that this condition shares features with both the Cournot and
529
+ | Bertrand models. On the one hand, the first term represents the direct effect of
530
+ | quantity on price, and it is reminiscent of the standard quantity setting equilibrium
531
+ | (Cournot). On the other hard, the second component represents the listener feedback
532
+ | loop and is reminiscent of the price setting model (Bertrand), because ad quantities
533
+ | function like prices in the demand for programming.
534
+ | In order to determine the impact of a merger on the equilibrium ad quantities
535
+ | supplied we need to know if they are strategic complements or substitutes. The
536
+ | duality described in the previous paragraph make it ambiguous. This is because
537
+ | in the Cournot model quantities are strategic substitutes and in the differentiated
538
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 11
539
+ blank |
540
+ |
541
+ |
542
+ text | product Bertrand model prices are strategic complements. Without knowing the
543
+ | relative strengths of the direct effects and the feedback loop, we cannot conclude
544
+ | whether a merger leads to an increase or decrease in ad quantity on the margin.
545
+ | Moreover, in the borderline case in which the effects cancel each other, a merger does
546
+ | not effect quantity at all; in this case, even though companies have market power
547
+ | over both consumers, they are unable to exercise it. Measuring these effects is critical
548
+ | for predicting the split of surplus between advertisers and listeners. When the direct
549
+ | effect is stronger, mergers lead to contraction in the ad quantity supplied and higher
550
+ | prices. This will benefit listeners but hurt advertisers. However, if the feedback loop
551
+ | is stronger than the direct effect then merger leads to more advertising and lower
552
+ | prices, benefiting advertisers and hurting listeners.
553
+ | Because the theory does not give a clear prediction about the split of surplus, I
554
+ | investigate this question empirically using a structural model. In the remainder of
555
+ | this section I put more structure on equations (2.1), (2.2) and (2.3), enabling separate
556
+ | identification of both sets of demand elasticities. I discover the relative strength of
557
+ | the direct and feedback effects and perform counterfactuals that quantify the extent
558
+ | of surplus reallocation.
559
+ blank |
560
+ |
561
+ title | 2.3.1 Industry setup
562
+ text | During each period t, the industry consists of M geographical markets that are char-
563
+ | acterized by a set of demographic covariates d ∈ Dm . Each market m can have up to
564
+ | Jm active radio stations and Km active owners. Each radio station is characterized by
565
+ | one of F possible programming formats. Station formats include the so-called “dark”
566
+ | format when a station is not operational The set of all station/format configurations
567
+ | m
568
+ | is given by FJ . Ownership structure is defined as a Km -element partition of sta-
569
+ | m
570
+ | tion/format configuration smt ∈ FJ . In an abuse of notation, I will consider smt
571
+ | to be a station/format configuration for market m at time t, as well as an owner-
572
+ | ship partition. Each member of the ownership partition (denoted as sk ) specifies the
573
+ | portfolio of stations owned by firm k.
574
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 12
575
+ blank |
576
+ |
577
+ |
578
+ text | The quality of the programming of radio station j is fully characterized by a one-
579
+ | dimensional quality measure ξj ∈ Ξ ⊂ R. The state of the industry at time time t
580
+ | in market m is therefore fully characterized by: a station/format configuration and
581
+ | ownership structure stm , vector of station quality measures ξ tm and market covariates
582
+ | dtm . In the next subsections I present a detailed model of listener demand, advertiser
583
+ | demand, and supply side. Throughout the description I take the triple (stm , ξ tm , dtm )
584
+ | as given and frequently omit market or time subscripts to simplify the notation.
585
+ blank |
586
+ |
587
+ title | 2.3.2 Listeners
588
+ text | This subsection describes the details of the demand for listenership introduced in
589
+ | equation (2.1). The model will be a variation on the random coefficient discrete
590
+ | choice setup proposed by Berry, Levinsohn, and Pakes (1995).
591
+ | I assume that each listener chooses only one radio station to listen to at a particular
592
+ | moment. Suppose that s is a set of active stations in the current market at a particular
593
+ | time. For any radio station j ∈ s, I define a vector ιj = (0, . . . , 1, . . . , 0) where 1 is
594
+ | placed in a position that indicates the format of station j.
595
+ | The utility of listener i listening to station j ∈ s is given by
596
+ blank |
597
+ text | L L
598
+ | uij = θ1i ιj − θ2i qj + θ3L FMj + ξj + ji (2.4)
599
+ blank |
600
+ text | L
601
+ | where θ2i is the individual listener’s demand sensitivity to adverting, qj the amount
602
+ | of advertising, ξj the unobserved station quality, ji an unobserved preference shock
603
+ | L
604
+ | (distributed type-1 extreme value), and finally θ1i is a vector of the individual listener’s
605
+ | random effects representing preferences for formats.
606
+ | I assume that the random coefficients can be decomposed as
607
+ blank |
608
+ text | L
609
+ | θ1i = θ1L + ΠDi + ν1i , Di ∼ Fm (Di |d), ν1i ∼ N (0, Σ1 )
610
+ blank |
611
+ text | and
612
+ | L
613
+ | θ2i = θ2L + ν2i , ν2i ∼ N (0, Σ2 )
614
+ blank |
615
+ text | where Σ1 is a diagonal matrix, Fm (Di |d) is an empirical distribution of demographic
616
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 13
617
+ blank |
618
+ |
619
+ |
620
+ text | characteristics, νi is unobserved taste shock, and Π is the matrix representing the
621
+ | correlation between demographic characteristics and format preferences. I assume
622
+ | that draws for νi are uncorrelated across time and markets.
623
+ | The random effects model allows for fairly flexible substitution patterns. For
624
+ | example, if a particular rock station increases its level of advertising, the model
625
+ | allows for consumers to switch proportionally to other rock stations depending on
626
+ | demographics.
627
+ | Following Berry, Levinsohn, and Pakes (1995), I can decompose the utility into a
628
+ | part that does not vary with consumer characteristics
629
+ blank |
630
+ text | δj = δ(qj |ιj , ξj , θL ) = θ1L ιi − θ2L qj + θ3L FMj + ξj
631
+ blank |
632
+ text | an interaction part
633
+ blank |
634
+ text | µji = µ(ιj , qj , ΠDi , νi ) = (ΠDi + ν1i )ιj + ν2i qj
635
+ blank |
636
+ text | and error term ji .
637
+ | Given this specification, and the fact that ji is distributed as an extreme value,
638
+ | one can derive the expected station rating conditional on a vector of advertising levels
639
+ | q, market structure s, a vector of unobserved station characteristics ξ, and market
640
+ | demographic characteristics d,
641
+ | Z Z
642
+ | L exp[δj + µji ]
643
+ | rj (q|s, ξ, d, θ ) = P dF (νi )dFm (Di |d)
644
+ | j 0 ∈s exp[δj 0 + µj 0 i ]
645
+ blank |
646
+ |
647
+ title | 2.3.3 Advertisers
648
+ text | In this subsection I present the details of the demand for advertising introduced in
649
+ | equation (2.2). The model captures several important features specific to the radio
650
+ | industry. In particular, the pricing is done on a per-listener basis, so that the price
651
+ | for a 60sec slot of advertising is a product of cost-per-point (CPP) and station rating
652
+ | (market share in percents). Moreover, radio stations have a direct market power over
653
+ | advertisers, so that CPP is a decreasing function of the ad quantities offered by a
654
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 14
655
+ blank |
656
+ |
657
+ |
658
+ text | station and its competitors. The simplest model that captures these features and is
659
+ | a good approximation of the industry is a linear inverse demand for advertising, such
660
+ | as !
661
+ | X
662
+ | pj = θ1A rj 1 − θ2A ωfmf 0 qf 0 (2.5)
663
+ | f 0 ∈F
664
+ blank |
665
+ text | where f is a format of station j, θ1A is a scaling factor for value of advertising, θ2A is
666
+ | a market power indicator and ωf f 0 ∈ Ω are weights indicating competition closeness,
667
+ | between formats f and f 0 .
668
+ | The weights ω are a key factor determining competition between formats and thus
669
+ | market power. They reflect the fact that some formats are further and others are closer
670
+ | substitutes for advertisers because of differences in the demographic composition of
671
+ | their listeners. In principle, one could proceed by estimating these weights from
672
+ | the data. However, here it is not feasible to do that because the available data
673
+ | do not contain radio station level advertising prices. Instead, I make additional
674
+ | assumptions that will enable me to compute the weights using publicly available data.
675
+ | The reminder of this subsection discusses the formula for the weights and provides
676
+ | an example supporting this intuition. The formal micro-model is given in Appendix
677
+ | A.1.
678
+ | Let there be A types of advertisers. Each type a ∈ A targets a certain demographic
679
+ | group(s) a. I.e. advertiser of type a gets positive utility only if a listener of type a
680
+ | hears an ad. Denote rf |a to be the probability that a listener of type a chooses format
681
+ | f and ra|f to be the probability that a random listener of format f is of type a.
682
+ | Advertisers take these numbers, along with station ratings rj , as given and decide on
683
+ | which station to advertise. This assumption is is motivated by the fact that about
684
+ | 75% is purchased by small local firms. Such firms’ advertising decisions are unlikely
685
+ | to influence prices and station ratings in the short run.
686
+ | This decision problem results in an inverse demand for advertising with weights
687
+ | ωjj 0 , that are given by
688
+ blank |
689
+ text | 1 X 
690
+ | ωf f 0 = P 2
691
+ | ra|f ra|f rf 0 |a (2.6)
692
+ | a∈A ra|f a∈A
693
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 15
694
+ blank |
695
+ |
696
+ |
697
+ text | The formal justification and derivation of this equation is given in Appendix A.1. The
698
+ | intuition behind it is that the total impact on the per-listener price of an ad in format
699
+ | f is a weighted average of impacts on the per-listener value of an ad for different types
700
+ | of advertisers. The weighting is done by the advertisers’ arrival rates, which are equal
701
+ | to the listeners’ arrival rates ra|f . For each advertiser of type a the change of value
702
+ | of an ad in format f , in response to a change of total quantity supplied in format f 0 ,
703
+ | is affected by two things: it is proportional to the probability of correct targeting in
704
+ | format f , given by ra|f , because advertisers are expected utility maximizers; and it
705
+ | is proportional to the share of advertising purchased by this advertiser in format f 0 ,
706
+ | given by rf 0 |a . Assembling these pieces together and normalizing the weights to sum
707
+ | to 1 gives equation (2.6).
708
+ | To illustrate how these weights work in practice, consider the following example.
709
+ | Suppose that there are only two possible formats of programming: Talk and Hits, and
710
+ | two types of consumers: Teens and Adults. Teens like mostly Hits format and Adults
711
+ | like Talk format. However, Adults like Hits more than Teens like Talk. Hypothetical
712
+ | numerical values of rf |a and ra|f are given in Table 2.1.
713
+ blank |
714
+ text | rf |a ra|f Ω
715
+ | Talk Hits Teens Adults Talk Hits
716
+ | Teens 1/5 4/5 Talk 1/4 3/4 Talk 0.56 0.44
717
+ | Adults 3/5 2/5 Hits 2/3 1/3 Hits 0.28 0.72
718
+ | Table 2.1: Simple example of advertising weights
719
+ blank |
720
+ text | In Table 2.1, the impact of Hits on the price of Talk is greater than the impact of
721
+ | Talk on the price of Hits. This is due to the fact that the quantity supplied in the Hits
722
+ | format affects Adult-targeting advertisers (who drive the price of the Talk format)
723
+ | to a much greater extent than ad quantity in Talk affects Teen-targeting advertisers
724
+ | (who drive the price of the Hits format). Moreover, because the weights sum up to
725
+ | 1, it must be that the own effect of Talk is weaker than that of Hits. This is exactly
726
+ | the essence of the mechanism behind Equation (2.6). More examples from the data
727
+ | with an extensive discussion are given in Section 2.6.
728
+ | In the next section I will combine demand for programming and advertising to
729
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 16
730
+ blank |
731
+ |
732
+ |
733
+ text | compose the profits of the radio station owners.
734
+ blank |
735
+ |
736
+ title | 2.3.4 Radio station owners
737
+ text | In this subsection I will describe a profit maximizing problem for the radio station
738
+ | owners. It will be a version of equation (2.3) that allows for non-zero cost in selling
739
+ | advertising and common radio station ownership. Given the advertising quantity
740
+ | choices of competing owners q−k , the profit of radio station owner k is given by
741
+ | X
742
+ | π̄k (qk |q−k , ξ, θ) = max rj (q|ξ, θL )pj qj − MCj (qj ) =
743
+ | {qj ;j∈sk }
744
+ | j∈sk
745
+ blank |
746
+ text | X X
747
+ | ! (2.7)
748
+ | = θ1A max L
749
+ | qj rj (q|ξ, θ ) 1 − θ2A ωfmf 0 qf 0 A C
750
+ | + Cj (qj |θ , θ )
751
+ | {qj ;j∈sk }
752
+ | j∈sk f 0 ∈F
753
+ blank |
754
+ |
755
+ text | where Cj (qj ) is the total cost of selling advertising. I assume constant marginal cost
756
+ | and allow for a firm level of unobserved cost heterogeneity ηj , i.e. Cj (qj |θA , θC ) =
757
+ | θ1A [θC + ηj ]qj .
758
+ | I assume that the markets are in a Cournot Nash Equilibrium. The first order
759
+ | conditions for profit optimization become
760
+ blank |  
761
+ text | X ∂rj 0
762
+ | rj pj + qj 0 A m
763
+ | pj 0 − rj 0 θ2 ωjj 0 − θC − ηj = 0 ∀k and j ∈ sk (2.8)
764
+ | j 0 ∈s
765
+ | ∂qj
766
+ | k
767
+ blank |
768
+ |
769
+ |
770
+ text | Additionally, I assume that station unobserved quality is exogenous but serially cor-
771
+ | related. It evolves according an AR(1) process such that
772
+ blank |
773
+ text | ξjt = ρξjt−1 + ζjt (2.9)
774
+ blank |
775
+ text | where ζjt is an exogenous innovation to station quality.
776
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 17
777
+ blank |
778
+ |
779
+ |
780
+ title | 2.4 Data description
781
+ text | I have constructed a panel of data on radio stations and radio station ownership
782
+ | merging data from two sources: BIA Financial Network Inc. and the SQAD Media
783
+ | Market Guide.
784
+ | BIAfn provided me data on: radio station ownership, revenues, market shares and
785
+ | formats. The data are a 1996-2006 panel covering each radio station in the market
786
+ | in 2006. The data are incomplete in the sense that I do not observe all the stations
787
+ | that exited the market between 1996 and 2006. According to Sweeting (2007) there
788
+ | were only 50 stations that exited during this period, mostly due to violations of FCC
789
+ | regulations. Because this number is small relative to the 11,000 stations in the sample,
790
+ | this omission is unlikely to significantly influence the results.
791
+ | The BIAfn data are supplemented with data on aggregate advertising prices. Un-
792
+ | fortunately, price data at the station level are not available. SQAD instead provides
793
+ | estimates of market prices that are obtained using proprietary formulas. According
794
+ | to anecdotal evidence, those estimates are widely recognized as the industry standard
795
+ | and are the best available data on market prices. Radio market prices are reported
796
+ | as a Cost per Rating Point (CPP). CPP is the cost of advertising per 1 percent of
797
+ | listenership. SQAD provides CPP broken down into daytime and demographic cat-
798
+ | egories. We will estimate station level prices from SQAD CPPs using radio station
799
+ | ratings that are broken down by time of day and demographics.
800
+ | An observation in my data is a radio station operating in a specific half-year and
801
+ | in a specific market. BIAfn and SQAD use Arbitron market definitions. An Arbitron
802
+ | market is in most cases a county or a metropolitan area. According to the surveys
803
+ | conducted by CRA International (2007) for the Canadian market (which is similar to
804
+ | the US market): “The majority of radio advertisers are local. They are only interested
805
+ | in advertising in their local area since most of their customers and potential buyers
806
+ | live in or very near their city.” In our analysis, I assume no interdependence between
807
+ | markets. To further assure that there is no overlap between markets, I use only the
808
+ | 88 market sub-selection that was developed in Sweeting (2007). Table 2.7 presents a
809
+ | list of the 88 markets, along with their populations.
810
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 18
811
+ blank |
812
+ |
813
+ text | 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006
814
+ | Number of
815
+ | 26.75 26.92 27.25 27.53 27.66 27.89 28.48 28.61 28.72 28.78 28.86
816
+ | stations
817
+ | Number of
818
+ | 16.58 15.55 14.94 14.21 13.29 13.03 13.16 12.96 12.73 12.52 12.48
819
+ | owners
820
+ | C3 0.77 0.83 0.88 0.91 0.97 0.95 0.93 0.93 0.93 0.93 0.90
821
+ | Number of
822
+ | 4.43 5.10 5.66 5.94 6.58 6.32 6.31 6.34 6.42 6.38 6.28
823
+ | stations owned
824
+ | Fraction of
825
+ | stations that 0.12 0.12 0.10 0.11 0.12 0.03 0.04 0.03 0.03 0.03 NaN
826
+ | changed ownership
827
+ | Fraction of
828
+ | stations that 0.11 0.11 0.13 0.12 0.12 0.13 0.10 0.11 0.11 0.11 NaN
829
+ | changed format
830
+ | Ad quantity 23.19 25.85 26.12 28.45 30.31 24.71 28.37 24.54 28.16 28.30 26.95
831
+ | Price divided by
832
+ | 1.00 0.96 1.08 1.10 1.26 1.51 1.42 1.51 1.39 1.37 1.43
833
+ | price in 1996
834
+ blank |
835
+ text | Table 2.2: Panel data descriptive statistics
836
+ blank |
837
+ text | To achieve a sharper identification of the random effects covariance matrix, I use
838
+ | listenership shares of different demographic groups in each of the formats that has
839
+ | been aggregated from the 100 biggest markets 2 . I observe listenership shares of
840
+ | different age/gender groups within each station format between 1998 and 2006, and
841
+ | shares for income, race and education groups between 2003 and 2006. Unfortunately,
842
+ | I do not observe a full matrix of market shares for all the combinations of demographic
843
+ | variables. For example, I do not see what the share of rock stations is among black,
844
+ | educated males. Instead I have shares for blacks, educated people, and males.
845
+ | Table 2.2 contains some basic aggregate statistics about the industry. The top
846
+ | part of the table documents changes in concentration of radio station ownership.
847
+ | The average number of stations owned in our dataset grew from 4.43 in 1996 to
848
+ | 6.28 in 2006. This ownership consolidation resulted in growth of the market share
849
+ | of the 3 biggest owners (C3) from 77% in 1996 to 90% in 2006, peaking at 97% in
850
+ | 2000. The middle part of the table contains the average percentages of stations that
851
+ | switched owners and that switched formats. Between 1996 and 2000 more than 10%
852
+ | of stations switched owners yearly. After 2000 the number dropped to below 4%.
853
+ | Greater concentration activity in the 1996-2000 period was also associated with more
854
+ | format switching. The percentage of stations that switched format peaked in 1998
855
+ | and 2001 at 13%.
856
+ meta | 2
857
+ text | Source: Arbitron Format Trends Report
858
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 19
859
+ blank |
860
+ |
861
+ |
862
+ title | 2.5 Estimation
863
+ text | The estimation of the model is done in two steps. In the first step, I estimate the
864
+ | demand model that includes parameters of the consumer utility θL (see equation
865
+ | (2.4)) and the unobserved station quality lag parameter ρ (see equation (3.1)). In
866
+ | the second step, we recover parameters of the inverse demand for advertising θA , wjj 0
867
+ | (see equation (2.5)) and cost parameters θC (see equation (2.7)).
868
+ blank |
869
+ |
870
+ title | 2.5.1 First stage
871
+ text | This stage provides the estimates of demand for radio programming θL . Estimation is
872
+ | done using the generalized method of simulated moments. I use two sets of moment
873
+ | conditions. The first set is based on the fact that innovation to station unobserved
874
+ | quality ξj has a mean of zero conditional on the instruments:
875
+ blank |
876
+ text | E[ξjt − ρξjt−1 |Z1 , θL ] = 0 (2.10)
877
+ blank |
878
+ text | This moment condition follows Berry, Levinsohn, and Pakes (1995) and extends it by
879
+ | explicitly introducing auto-correlation of ξ. I use instruments for advertising quantity
880
+ | since it is likely to be correlated with unobserved station quality. My instruments
881
+ | include: lagged mean and second central moment of competitors’ advertising quantity,
882
+ | lagged market HHIs and lagged number and cumulative market share of other stations
883
+ | in the same format. These are valid instruments under the assumption that ξt follows
884
+ | an AR(1) process and the fact that decisions about portfolio selection are made before
885
+ | decisions about advertising.
886
+ | A second set of moment conditions is based on demographic listenership data.
887
+ | Let Rf c be the national market share of format f among listeners possessing certain
888
+ | demographic characteristics c. The population moment conditions are
889
+ blank |
890
+ text | exp[δjmt + µmt ji ]
891
+ | Z Z Z
892
+ | P mt mt
893
+ | t
894
+ | dF (νi )dFct (Dic , m)dt = Rf c (2.11)
895
+ | t t ,m)
896
+ | (Dic νi 0
897
+ | j ∈s mt exp[δ j 0 + µ ij 0 ]
898
+ blank |
899
+ text | where Fct (Di , m) is a national distribution of people who possess characteristic c at
900
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 20
901
+ blank |
902
+ |
903
+ |
904
+ text | time t. Each person is characterized by the demographic characteristics Di and the
905
+ | market m they belong to.
906
+ | For each time t and demographic characteristic c, I draw I observation pairs
907
+ | t
908
+ | (Dic , m) from the nationally aggregated CPS. Let g = (g1 , g2 ) represent the empirical
909
+ | moments and W be a weighting matrix. I estimate the model by using the constrained
910
+ | optimization procedure:
911
+ blank |
912
+ text | min g 0 W g
913
+ | θL ,ξ,g
914
+ blank |
915
+ text | Subject to:
916
+ | r̂jmt (qmt |smt , ξmt , dmt , θL ) = rjmt ∀t, m
917
+ | (2.12)
918
+ | exp[δjmt + µmt ji ]
919
+ | Z
920
+ | 1 X X
921
+ | P mt mt
922
+ | dF (νi ) − Rf c = g1 ∀c
923
+ | TI t t ν i j 0 ∈smt exp[δ j 0 + µ ij 0 ]
924
+ | (Dic ,m)
925
+ | 1
926
+ | Z1 (ξ − ρLξ) = g2
927
+ | size of ξ
928
+ blank |
929
+ text | where L is a lag operator that converts the vector ξ into one-period lagged values. If
930
+ | the radio station did not exist in the previous period, the lag operator has a value of
931
+ | zero. Integration with respect to demographics when calculating the first constraint is
932
+ | obtained by drawing from the CPS in the particular market and period. This way of
933
+ | integrating allows us to maintain proper correlations between possessed demographic
934
+ | characteristics. The same is true when obtaining the data set Dict . When computing
935
+ | the interaction terms µ in the second constraint, I draw one vector νi from the normal
936
+ | distribution for each Dict .
937
+ blank |
938
+ |
939
+ title | 2.5.2 Second stage
940
+ text | The second stage of the estimation obtains the competition matrix Ω and the pa-
941
+ | rameters of demand for advertising θA . The estimation is done separately for every
942
+ | market, thereby allowing for different Ω and θA .
943
+ | To compute the matrices Ωm for each market I use the specification layed out in
944
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 21
945
+ blank |
946
+ |
947
+ |
948
+ text | section 2.3.3. The elements of the matrix Ω are specified as
949
+ blank |
950
+ text | 1 X 
951
+ | ωf f 0 = P 2
952
+ | ra|f ra|f rf 0 |a
953
+ | a∈A ra|f a∈A
954
+ blank |
955
+ |
956
+ text | following equation (2.6). The rf |a are advertisers’ beliefs about listeners’ preferences
957
+ | for formats. These are constant across markets. To recognize that advertisers know
958
+ | the demographic composition of each market I allow for market specific listener arrival
959
+ | rates for each format rfm|a . However, I assume that the advertisers compute those
960
+ | values by using Radio Today reports and the Current Population Survey. After
961
+ | computing weights, I treat Ωm as exogenous and fixed in all of the following steps 3 .
962
+ | After computing matrices Ω, I estimate θA . Using estimates of demand for radio
963
+ | programming θL from the first stage, I compute ratings for each station conditioned
964
+ | on the counterfactual advertising quantities. I use the set of 3M moment conditions
965
+ blank |
966
+ text | Em [η m |Z2 , θA , θC ] = 0 ∀m ∈ M (2.13)
967
+ blank |
968
+ text | where the integral is taken with respect to time and stations in each market. ηjtm is
969
+ | an unobserved shock to marginal cost defined in equation (2.5). The Z2 are three
970
+ | instruments: a column of ones, the AM/FM dummy and number of competitors in
971
+ | the same format. They are uncorrelated with η m under the IID assumption, but
972
+ | are correlated with the current choice of quantity because they describe the market
973
+ | structure.
974
+ | We back out ηjtm using FOCs for owner’s profit maximization (see equation (2.7))
975
+ blank |
976
+ text | ∂rjt 0 t
977
+ | X  
978
+ | ηjt = rjt ptj + qjt 0 A t m C
979
+ | p 0 − θ2m rj 0 ωf f 0 − θm ∀t ∈ T, k ∈ Ktm , j ∈ stm (2.14)
980
+ | ∂qjt j k
981
+ | j 0 ∈stm
982
+ | k
983
+ blank |
984
+ |
985
+ text | A A C
986
+ | Since the equation does not depend on θ1m , I can use it to estimate θ2m and θm . During
987
+ | the estimation, I allow for a different value of marginal cost for each market. I allow
988
+ meta | 3
989
+ text | Such an approach potentially ignores possible variance of the Ωm estimator. The source of
990
+ | this variance might come from the finiteness of the CPS dataset and the distribution of Arbitron
991
+ | estimates.
992
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 22
993
+ blank |
994
+ |
995
+ |
996
+ text | for 3 different values for the slope of inverse demand depending on the population of
997
+ | the market (up to 500 people, between 500 and 1500, and 1500 or more). Ratings
998
+ | and derivatives of ratings in the equation (2.14) are calculated using the estimates of
999
+ | θL and ξ from the first stage. Demographic draws are taken from the CPS and are
1000
+ | A
1001
+ | independent of those used in the first stage. Given the estimates of θ2m and θC , I
1002
+ | A
1003
+ | can back out θ1m by equating the observed average revenue in each market with its
1004
+ | predicted counterpart.
1005
+ | Next I discuss a variation in the data that identifies parameters θA and θC . The
1006
+ | intuition for such identification is that estimating Equation 2.14 can be regarded as a
1007
+ | C
1008
+ | linear regression in which θm is an intercept and θ2A is a coefficient of a variable that
1009
+ | is a function of supplied quantity. In this case, the mean deviation of FOCs from zero
1010
+ | C
1011
+ | in each market identifies the intercept θm . The slope parameter θ2A is identified by the
1012
+ | size of the response of the firm to changes in quantity supplied by its competitors due
1013
+ | to change in the market structure or demographics. Such a response, as mentioned
1014
+ | in Section 2.3, is composed of listeners’ demand feedback and the direct effect of
1015
+ | quantity on CPP. Elasticity of listeners’ demand, that determines the strength of the
1016
+ | feedback, is consistently estimated in the first step. Therefore, one can subtract the
1017
+ | difference out the feedback effect from the total response observed in the data. This
1018
+ | allows to obtain the strength of the direct effect that directly identifies the slope of
1019
+ | the CPP, θ2A . For example, if we look at the response of ad quantity reacting to the
1020
+ | merger, the slope of listeners’ demand alone predicts large increases in ad quantity.
1021
+ | However in the data, we observe smaller increases or even decrease in the quantity
1022
+ | supplied, depending on the market. Those differences are rationalized by a negative
1023
+ | value of CPP slope, θ2A .
1024
+ blank |
1025
+ |
1026
+ title | 2.6 Results
1027
+ text | This section presents estimates of the structural parameters. The next subsection
1028
+ | discusses listeners’ demand parameters. This is followed by results concerning adver-
1029
+ | tisers’ demand and marker power. The last subsection contains estimates of marginal
1030
+ | cost and profit margin (before subtracting fixed cost).
1031
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 23
1032
+ blank |
1033
+ |
1034
+ |
1035
+ title | 2.6.1 Listeners’ demand
1036
+ text | Table 2.3 contains estimates of demand parameters for radio programming. The esti-
1037
+ | mate of the mean effect of advertising on listeners’ utility is negative and statistically
1038
+ | significant. This is consistent with the belief that radio listeners have a disutility for
1039
+ | advertising. When it comes to the mean effects of programming formats, Contempo-
1040
+ | rary Hit Radio format gives the most utility, while the News/Talk format gives the
1041
+ | least.
1042
+ | The second column of Table 2.3 contains variances of random effects for station
1043
+ | formats. The higher a format’s variance, the more persistent are the tastes of listeners
1044
+ | for that format. For example, in response to an increased amount of advertising, if
1045
+ | the variance of the random effect for that format is high, listeners tend to switch
1046
+ | to a station of the same format. The estimates also suggest that tastes for the
1047
+ | Alternative/Urban format are the most persistent.
1048
+ | Table 2.4 contains estimates of interactions between listener characteristics and
1049
+ | format dummies. The majority of the parameters are consistent with intuition. For
1050
+ | example, younger people are more willing to choose a CHR format while older people
1051
+ | go for News/Talk. The negative coefficients on the interaction of Hispanic format
1052
+ | with education and income suggests that less educated Hispanic people with lower
1053
+ | income are more willing to listen to Hispanic stations. For blacks, I find a disutility
1054
+ | for Country, Rock and Hispanic, and a high utility for Urban. This is consistent
1055
+ | with the the fact that Urban radio stations play mostly rap, hip-hop and soul music
1056
+ | performed by black artists.
1057
+ blank |
1058
+ |
1059
+ title | 2.6.2 Advertisers’ demand
1060
+ text | Tables 2.5 presents the weights for selected markets representing large, medium and
1061
+ | small listener populations. They were computed using the 1999 edition of Radio
1062
+ | Today publication and Common Population Survey aggregated from 1996 to 2006.
1063
+ | It is interesting to compute a total impact coefficient that is the sum of all the
1064
+ | columns of the table for each format. Not surprisingly, general interest formats like
1065
+ | AC and News/Talk have the biggest impact on the price of advertising, while Spanish
1066
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 24
1067
+ blank |
1068
+ |
1069
+ |
1070
+ |
1071
+ text | Mean Effects (θ1L ) Random Effects (Σ1 )
1072
+ | −1.106∗∗∗ 0.030∗∗∗
1073
+ | Advertising (0.002) (0.009)
1074
+ | 0.861∗∗∗
1075
+ | AM/FM (0.000)
1076
+ | -
1077
+ | AC,
1078
+ | SmoothJazz, −2.431∗∗∗ 0.043∗∗∗
1079
+ | (0.008) (0.004)
1080
+ | and New AC
1081
+ | ∗∗∗
1082
+ | Rock −1.559 0.004
1083
+ | (0.140) (0.020)
1084
+ blank |
1085
+ text | −0.179∗∗∗ 0.009∗
1086
+ | CHR (0.025) (0.006)
1087
+ | ∗∗∗
1088
+ | Alternative −2.339 0.348∗∗∗
1089
+ | Urban (0.026) (0.008)
1090
+ | ∗∗∗
1091
+ | −4.678 0.024∗∗∗
1092
+ | News/Talk (0.010) (0.002)
1093
+ blank |
1094
+ text | Country −2.301∗∗∗ 0.011∗∗∗
1095
+ | (0.006) (0.003)
1096
+ blank |
1097
+ text | Spanish −1.619∗∗∗ 0.011∗∗∗
1098
+ | (0.004) (0.001)
1099
+ blank |
1100
+ text | −4.657∗∗∗ 0.005∗∗∗
1101
+ | Other (0.004) (0.002)
1102
+ blank |
1103
+ text | 0.568∗∗∗
1104
+ | ρ (0.091)
1105
+ | -
1106
+ blank |
1107
+ |
1108
+ |
1109
+ text | Table 2.3: Estimates of mean and random effects of demand for radio programming.
1110
+ | Stars indicate parameter significance when testing with 0.1, 0.05 and 0.01 test sizes.
1111
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 25
1112
+ blank |
1113
+ |
1114
+ text | Demographics characteristics (Π)
1115
+ | Age Sex Education Income Black Spanish
1116
+ | AC,
1117
+ | SmoothJazz, −0.171∗∗∗ −0.341∗∗∗ 0.602∗∗∗ −0.024∗∗∗ 0.121∗∗∗ −1.014∗∗∗
1118
+ | (0.001) (0.064) (0.013) (0.003) (0.012) (0.008)
1119
+ | and New AC
1120
+ | Rock −0.645∗∗∗ 0.399∗∗∗ 0.861∗∗∗ −0.147∗∗∗ −1.359∗∗∗ −1.643∗∗∗
1121
+ | (0.072) (0.031) (0.006) (0.045) (0.007) (0.003)
1122
+ blank |
1123
+ text | −2.541∗∗∗ 0.477∗∗∗ 1.772∗∗∗ −0.291∗∗∗ 1.946∗∗∗ 0.463∗∗∗
1124
+ | CHR (0.015) (0.080) (0.006) (0.005) (0.015) (0.001)
1125
+ | ∗∗∗ ∗∗∗ ∗∗∗ ∗∗∗ ∗∗∗
1126
+ | Alternative −0.817 1.350 0.583 −0.141 3.152 0.267∗∗∗
1127
+ | Urban (0.008) (0.018) (0.025) (0.002) (0.005) (0.027)
1128
+ blank |
1129
+ |
1130
+ text | News/Talk 0.329∗∗∗ 1.228∗∗∗ 0.237∗∗∗ 0.093∗∗∗ −0.321∗∗∗ −1.649∗∗∗
1131
+ | (0.002) (0.012) (0.009) (0.005) (0.001) (0.005)
1132
+ blank |
1133
+ text | Country 0.062∗∗∗ −0.149∗∗∗ 0.133∗∗∗ −0.125∗∗∗ −1.548∗∗∗ −1.717∗∗∗
1134
+ | (0.004) (0.022) (0.004) (0.003) (0.009) (0.002)
1135
+ blank |
1136
+ text | −0.024∗ −0.908∗∗∗ −0.328∗∗∗ −1.140∗∗∗ −2.560∗∗∗ 0.797∗∗∗
1137
+ | Spanish (0.013) (0.012) (0.018) (0.002) (0.004) (0.003)
1138
+ blank |
1139
+ text | 0.263 0.624∗∗∗ 0.338∗∗∗ −0.031 0.498∗∗∗ 0.238∗∗∗
1140
+ | Other (0.373) (0.003) (0.006) (0.063) (0.001) (0.002)
1141
+ blank |
1142
+ |
1143
+ |
1144
+ |
1145
+ text | Table 2.4: Interaction terms between listeners’ demographics and taste for radio
1146
+ | programming.
1147
+ blank |
1148
+ text | format has the smallest. The values on the diagonals of the matrices represent the
1149
+ | formats’ own effect of the quantity of advertising supplied on per-listener price. They
1150
+ | are usually bigger than the off-diagonal values, that suggests that it is mostly the
1151
+ | ad quantity in the same format that influences a per-listener price. In accord with
1152
+ | an intuition, the formats with the most demographically homogenous listener pools,
1153
+ | Urban/Alternative and Spanish, have the highest values of the own effects. On the
1154
+ | other hand, general interest formats like CHR and Rock are charaterized by the
1155
+ | smallest values of the own effect, measuring the fact that their target population of
1156
+ | listeners is more dispersed across other formats. For cross effects, one notices that
1157
+ | News/Talk is close to AC and Urban is close to CHR. This can be explained by, for
1158
+ | example, the age of the listeners. In the former case the formats appeal to an older
1159
+ | population while in the latter case to a younger one.
1160
+ | Estimates of the slope of inverse demand are presented in Table 2.6. In mar-
1161
+ | kets with less than 0.5m people radio stations have considerable control over the
1162
+ | per-listener price. However, such control significantly drops in markets from 0.5m
1163
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 26
1164
+ blank |
1165
+ |
1166
+ text | Los Angeles, CA
1167
+ | AC
1168
+ | Alternative
1169
+ | SmoothJazz Rock CHR News/Talk Country Spanish Other
1170
+ | Urban
1171
+ | New AC
1172
+ | AC
1173
+ | SmoothJazz 0.22 0.10 0.11 0.09 0.17 0.14 0.00 0.17
1174
+ | New AC
1175
+ | Rock 0.15 0.21 0.12 0.09 0.16 0.13 0.01 0.12
1176
+ | CHR 0.18 0.12 0.16 0.16 0.10 0.13 0.03 0.13
1177
+ | Alternative
1178
+ | 0.11 0.05 0.17 0.44 0.06 0.05 0.00 0.12
1179
+ | Urban
1180
+ | News/Talk 0.17 0.10 0.05 0.05 0.30 0.13 0.00 0.21
1181
+ | Country 0.16 0.10 0.09 0.07 0.15 0.22 0.01 0.21
1182
+ | Spanish 0.03 0.04 0.11 0.02 0.01 0.03 0.72 0.04
1183
+ | Other 0.18 0.07 0.06 0.08 0.20 0.17 0.00 0.23
1184
+ | Total impact 1.20 0.79 0.87 0.99 1.15 1.00 0.77 1.23
1185
+ blank |
1186
+ |
1187
+ text | Atlanta, GA
1188
+ | AC
1189
+ | Alternative
1190
+ | SmoothJazz Rock CHR News/Talk Country Spanish Other
1191
+ | Urban
1192
+ | New AC
1193
+ | AC
1194
+ | SmoothJazz 0.20 0.10 0.12 0.09 0.14 0.18 0.00 0.18
1195
+ | New AC
1196
+ | Rock 0.14 0.21 0.13 0.10 0.12 0.17 0.01 0.13
1197
+ | CHR 0.17 0.13 0.17 0.14 0.09 0.17 0.01 0.13
1198
+ | Alternative
1199
+ | 0.11 0.06 0.16 0.40 0.06 0.08 0.00 0.13
1200
+ | Urban
1201
+ | News/Talk 0.16 0.10 0.05 0.05 0.25 0.17 0.00 0.22
1202
+ | Country 0.15 0.09 0.08 0.06 0.13 0.26 0.01 0.22
1203
+ | Spanish 0.04 0.04 0.12 0.02 0.01 0.03 0.71 0.03
1204
+ | Other 0.16 0.07 0.06 0.07 0.16 0.23 0.01 0.25
1205
+ | Total impact 1.11 0.78 0.88 0.94 0.95 1.31 0.75 1.29
1206
+ blank |
1207
+ |
1208
+ text | Knoxville, TN
1209
+ | AC
1210
+ | Alternative
1211
+ | SmoothJazz Rock CHR News/Talk Country Spanish Other
1212
+ | Urban
1213
+ | New AC
1214
+ | AC
1215
+ | SmoothJazz 0.20 0.11 0.16 0.11 0.10 0.16 0.01 0.16
1216
+ | New AC
1217
+ | Rock 0.13 0.21 0.14 0.11 0.10 0.18 0.01 0.12
1218
+ | CHR 0.16 0.12 0.18 0.14 0.08 0.17 0.02 0.13
1219
+ | Alternative
1220
+ | 0.12 0.06 0.16 0.38 0.06 0.08 0.00 0.13
1221
+ | Urban
1222
+ | News/Talk 0.16 0.13 0.10 0.09 0.17 0.16 0.01 0.18
1223
+ | Country 0.15 0.13 0.14 0.10 0.09 0.22 0.01 0.16
1224
+ | Spanish 0.05 0.05 0.11 0.02 0.02 0.04 0.66 0.05
1225
+ | Other 0.17 0.09 0.11 0.12 0.12 0.18 0.01 0.21
1226
+ | Total impact 1.12 0.90 1.11 1.05 0.74 1.21 0.72 1.14
1227
+ blank |
1228
+ |
1229
+ |
1230
+ |
1231
+ text | Table 2.5: Product closeness matrices for chosen markets
1232
+ blank |
1233
+ text | to 2m people, and it disappears completely in markets with more than 2m people,
1234
+ | making radio stations essentially price takers. I suspect that this phenomenon can be
1235
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 27
1236
+ blank |
1237
+ |
1238
+ text | Market population less than .5m between .5m and 1.5m more than 1.5m
1239
+ | 1.34 (0.046) 0.35 (0.026) 0.00 (0.008)
1240
+ blank |
1241
+ text | Table 2.6: Slope of the inverse demand for ads θ2A , by market size
1242
+ blank |
1243
+ text | explained by the fact that in larger markets there are more outside options for radio
1244
+ | advertising. This can lead to tougher competition between media outlets, and make
1245
+ | the inverse demand for advertising flatter. However, in small markets radio might be
1246
+ | a primary advertising channel, because other media like the Internet or billboards are
1247
+ | not as widespread. This gives radio stations more control over price.
1248
+ blank |
1249
+ |
1250
+ title | 2.6.3 Supply
1251
+ text | The marginal costs of selling advertising minutes are presented in Table 2.7. The
1252
+ | values of this cost range from $356 per minute of advertising sold in Los Angeles,
1253
+ | CA to $11 in Ft. Myers, FL. 66% of the variation in marginal cost can be explained
1254
+ | by variation in market population. A population increase of one thousand translates
1255
+ | to about a 2 cent increase in marginal cost (with t-stat equal to 12). The high cor-
1256
+ | relation between population and marginal costs can be explained by the fact that
1257
+ | revenues per-minute of advertising are an increasing function of total market popula-
1258
+ | tion. Suppose this surplus is split between radio station owners and advertisers’ sales
1259
+ | people according to the Nash Bargaining solution. In this case, the high correlation
1260
+ | of revenue with population will translate into a high correlation of marginal cost with
1261
+ | population.
1262
+ | From the revenues and marginal cost estimates, I can calculate variable profit
1263
+ | margins. These are presented in the last last column of Table 2.7. The range is
1264
+ | from 92% in Shreveport, LA to 15% in Honolulu, HI and Reno, NV. It is interesting
1265
+ | that 38% of the profit margin variation can be explained by the variance in total ad
1266
+ | quantity supplied and markets with high profit margins firms supply more advertising.
1267
+ | The marginal effect of extra minute per day of broadcasted advertising translates into
1268
+ | 0.6% of extra profit margin.
1269
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS
1270
+ text | Marginal Profit Marginal Profit
1271
+ | Market Population (mil) Market Population
1272
+ | cost ($ per-miute) margin cost margin
1273
+ | Los Angeles, CA 13,155 356.4 (5.15) 30% Tulsa, OK 856 72.8 (2.13) 21%
1274
+ | Chicago, IL 9,341 180.0 (2.70) 34% Knoxville, TN 785 54.3 (1.99) 27%
1275
+ | Dallas-Ft. Worth, TX 5,847 198.6 (5.60) 28% Albuquerque, NM 740 27.4 (1.04) 36%
1276
+ | Houston-Galveston, TX 5,279 199.7 (4.20) 28% Ft. Myers-Naples-Marco Island, FL 737 11.3 (0.94) 57%
1277
+ | Atlanta, GA 4,710 95.4 (3.37) 43% Omaha-Council Bluffs, NE-IA 728 48.0 (0.91) 28%
1278
+ | Boston, MA 4,532 172.2 (3.68) 33% Harrisburg-Lebanon-Carlisle, PA 649 29.7 (1.44) 42%
1279
+ | Miami-Ft, FL 4,174 134.3 (3.70) 28% El Paso, TX 619 41.8 (4.12) 20%
1280
+ | Seattle-Tacoma, WA 3,776 128.7 (2.21) 29% Quad Cities, IA-IL 618 51.3 (1.30) 23%
1281
+ | Phoenix, AZ 3,638 63.7 (1.84) 39% Wichita, KS 598 38.9 (0.85) 25%
1282
+ | Minneapolis-St. Paul, MN 3,155 160.8 (4.66) 26% Little Rock, AR 577 45.2 (1.64) 26%
1283
+ | St. Louis, MO 2,689 190.6 (5.38) 18% Columbia, SC 577 60.0 (2.10) 23%
1284
+ | Tampa-St, FL 2,649 102.7 (2.09) 26% Charleston, SC 569 59.6 (1.74) 19%
1285
+ | Denver-Boulder, CO 2,604 99.9 (1.40) 32% Des Moines, IA 564 21.3 (0.92) 40%
1286
+ | Portland, OR 2,352 48.6 (1.35) 41% Spokane, WA 540 24.5 (0.63) 28%
1287
+ | Cleveland, OH 2,134 170.6 (3.34) 24% Madison, WI 520 93.6 (3.02) 22%
1288
+ | Charlotte, NC-SC 2,127 67.1 (1.96) 38% Augusta, GA 510 30.9 (0.60) 24%
1289
+ | Sacramento, CA 2,100 47.6 (1.30) 42% Ft. Wayne, IN 509 37.8 (1.35) 27%
1290
+ | Salt Lake City, UT 1,924 58.1 (1.19) 26% Lexington-Fayette, KY 495 36.8 (1.59) 35%
1291
+ | San Antonio, TX 1,900 75.0 (2.27) 24% Chattanooga, TN 471 41.5 (2.53) 29%
1292
+ | Kansas City, MO-KS 1,871 152.5 (2.87) 19% Boise, ID 469 46.2 (3.73) 30%
1293
+ | Las Vegas, NV 1,752 47.7 (1.49) 32% Jackson, MS 453 18.6 (2.03) 59%
1294
+ | Milwaukee-Racine, WI 1,713 74.6 (1.27) 25% Eugene-Springfield, OR 439 27.4 (1.29) 31%
1295
+ | Orlando, FL 1,686 42.4 (1.77) 41% Reno, NV 400 99.7 (1.64) 15%
1296
+ | Columbus, OH 1,685 70.2 (1.53) 30% Shreveport, LA 359 19.8 (4.25) 92%
1297
+ | Indianapolis, IN 1,602 86.8 (2.32) 26% Fayetteville, NC 337 38.1 (2.48) 46%
1298
+ | Norfolk, VA 1,583 196.8 (4.64) 17% Springfield, MA 336 20.8 (0.87) 55%
1299
+ | Nashville, TN 1,342 40.5 (1.84) 38% Macon, GA 276 34.4 (2.29) 26%
1300
+ | Greensboro-Winston, NC 1,329 53.5 (2.34) 32% Binghamton, NY 255 37.5 (1.51) 27%
1301
+ | New Orleans, LA 1,294 91.2 (2.44) 24% Lubbock, TX 248 57.7 (1.98) 18%
1302
+ | Memphis, TN 1,278 53.2 (1.82) 30% Odessa-Midland, TX 231 21.4 (0.99) 27%
1303
+ | Jacksonville, FL 1,271 66.1 (1.64) 29% Fargo-Moorhead, ND-MN 200 48.6 (2.42) 25%
1304
+ | Oklahoma City, OK 1,268 75.6 (1.35) 25% Medford-Ashland, OR 184 27.7 (0.90) 28%
1305
+ | Buffalo-Niagara Falls, NY 1,150 141.5 (3.63) 19% Duluth-Superior, MN-WI 159 43.3 (0.79) 20%
1306
+ | Louisville, KY 1,100 92.9 (2.36) 21% Parkersburg-Marietta, WV-OH 157 31.7 (1.41) 21%
1307
+ | Richmond, VA 1,066 55.3 (1.47) 28% Abilene, TX 149 23.0 (1.14) 26%
1308
+ | Birmingham, AL 1,030 85.8 (2.50) 24% Eau Claire, WI 149 31.6 (2.77) 28%
1309
+ | Honolulu, HI 938 78.2 (2.39) 15% Williamsport, PA 130 31.0 (1.13) 23%
1310
+ | Albany, NY 909 113.9 (3.18) 16% Monroe, LA 124 14.2 (1.49) 64%
1311
+ | Grand Junction, CO 902 24.5 (0.67) 24% Sioux City, IA 118 26.1 (0.96) 24%
1312
+ | Tucson, AZ 870 41.1 (0.93) 27% San Angelo, TX 104 26.4 (1.36) 16%
1313
+ | Grand Rapids, MI 864 37.9 (0.79) 38% Bismarck, ND 99 32.8 (1.65) 22%
1314
+ blank |
1315
+ |
1316
+ text | Table 2.7: Estimated marginal cost (in dollars per minute of broadcasted advertising) and profit margins (before
1317
+ | subtracting the fixed cost) for a chosen set of markets
1318
+ blank |
1319
+ |
1320
+ |
1321
+ |
1322
+ meta | 28
1323
+ | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 29
1324
+ blank |
1325
+ |
1326
+ text | Consumer Advertiser Mean price
1327
+ | Average ad load Advertising minutes
1328
+ | surplus surplus index
1329
+ | Impact of
1330
+ | ownership change and 6.6pdm -6.4pdm -158.3m -2,491min
1331
+ | +0.60%
1332
+ | format switching +1.3% -12.6% -16.3% -1.5%
1333
+ | No ad adjustment
1334
+ | Impact of -1.9pdm 1.6pdm -146.1m -9,838min
1335
+ | +2.09%
1336
+ | ad adjustment -0.4% +3.6% -18.0% -5.9%
1337
+ | Total impact of
1338
+ | ownership change 4.7pdm -4.8pdm -304.4m -12,329min
1339
+ | +2.67%
1340
+ | format switching and +0.9% -9.5% -31.4% -7.3%
1341
+ | ad adjustment
1342
+ blank |
1343
+ text | Table 2.8: Counterfactuals for all markets
1344
+ blank |
1345
+ title | 2.7 Counterfactual experiments
1346
+ text | In this section I investigate the impact of consolidation on listener and advertiser
1347
+ | welfare. First, I investigate the changes in the surplus of listeners and advertisers. In
1348
+ | particular, I calculate how much market power was exercised on both of those groups.
1349
+ | Second, I decompose market power into a variety component and extra market power
1350
+ | that is manifested in changes in quantity supplied.
1351
+ | Before performing counterfactual calculations, consider descriptive relationships
1352
+ | between concentration and prices. First, I regressed market Price Per Rating Point
1353
+ | on a market’s HHI, including market fixed effects. I find that higher concentration is
1354
+ | correlated with higher prices in the advertising market, suggesting that radio station
1355
+ | owners are exercising some amount of market power on advertisers. Second, I re-
1356
+ | gressed total advertising supplied on the market’s HHI with market dummies. Here I
1357
+ | get a coefficient of 1.65(0.3). This is evidence of market power in the listener market.
1358
+ | Because market power appears to be present in both market segments, I cannot defi-
1359
+ | nitely conclude who had more surplus extracted by radio station owners if I just use
1360
+ | quantities and prices. In the next subsection I present the structural counterfactuals
1361
+ | that answer this question.
1362
+ blank |
1363
+ |
1364
+ title | 2.7.1 Impact of mergers on consumer surplus
1365
+ text | To isolate the impact of the Telecom Act on a surplus division between advertisers
1366
+ | and listeners, I perform a counterfactual in which I recompute new equilibrium ad
1367
+ | quantities under the old 1996 ownership structure and 1996 formats. This calculation
1368
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 30
1369
+ blank |
1370
+ |
1371
+ text | Consumer Advertiser Mean price
1372
+ | Average ad load Advertising minutes
1373
+ | surplus surplus index
1374
+ | Impact of
1375
+ | ownership change and 11.7pdm -5.4pdm -118.1m -737min
1376
+ | +1.34%
1377
+ | format switching +2.5% -17.3% -15.8% -1.0%
1378
+ | No ad adjustment
1379
+ | Impact of 1.2pdm -2.2pdm -119.4m -8,216min
1380
+ | +5.66%
1381
+ | ad adjustment +0.3% -8.4% -19.0% -11.7%
1382
+ | Total impact of
1383
+ | ownership change 12.9pdm -7.5pdm -237.5m -8,953min
1384
+ | +6.99%
1385
+ | format switching and +2.8% -24.2% -31.8% -12.6%
1386
+ | ad adjustment
1387
+ blank |
1388
+ text | Table 2.9: Counterfactuals for small markets (less than 500k people)
1389
+ | Consumer Advertiser Mean price
1390
+ | Average ad load Advertising minutes
1391
+ | surplus surplus index
1392
+ | Impact of
1393
+ | ownership change and 2.6pdm -6.0pdm -1.0m -835min
1394
+ | +0.01%
1395
+ | format switching +0.5% -11.0% -12.8% -2.0%
1396
+ | No ad adjustment
1397
+ | Impact of -4.4pdm 4.6pdm 0.7m 3,081min
1398
+ | -0.02%
1399
+ | ad adjustment -0.8% +9.5% +9.9% +7.7%
1400
+ | Total impact of
1401
+ | ownership change -1.8pdm -1.4pdm -0.3m 2,245min
1402
+ | -0.01%
1403
+ | format switching and -0.3% -2.5% -4.2% +5.5%
1404
+ | ad adjustment
1405
+ blank |
1406
+ text | Table 2.10: Counterfactuals for large markets (more than 2,000k people)
1407
+ blank |
1408
+ text | is motivated by the fact that in 1996 many markets were at their ownership caps.
1409
+ | The total impact of consolidation on advertiser and listener welfare is presented
1410
+ | in the last row of Table 2.8. It turns out that mergers decrased total ad quantity
1411
+ | by roughtly 14 thousand minutes. That resulted in lowering average ad exposure
1412
+ | by 4.8 persons-day-minutes (pdm), which is about 10% of the total ad load. The
1413
+ | changes translated to about a 4.7 pdm increase in consumer welfare. Because we
1414
+ | do not observe dollar prices in the listenership market we cannot compute the dollar
1415
+ | value of this compensating variation. However, we can compute a rough estimate
1416
+ | using the prices for the satellite radio. If we assume people buy satelite radio just
1417
+ | to avoid advertising, we get a rough estimate of 1.5 cents per minute, or 730million
1418
+ | dollars for each person-day-minute per year. The total effect would amount to $3.5b.
1419
+ | This is of course a very loose upper bound on the overall welfare gain, however if
1420
+ | make a conservative assumption that only 10% of the value of satellite radio is lack
1421
+ | of advertising, we get $350m.
1422
+ | For advertisers, a decrease in quantity supplied leads to about 2.57% increase in
1423
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 31
1424
+ blank |
1425
+ |
1426
+ |
1427
+ text | per-listener prices, or a $300m decrease in advertiser surplus. I therefore conclude
1428
+ | that the Telecom Act lead to a reallocation of surplus from advertisers to listenerss.
1429
+ | Moreover, because the gain by listeners ($350m) is larger than the surplus lost by
1430
+ | advertisers, I find that the Act created new surplus. This increase can be explained
1431
+ | by the fact that listeners are more annoyed by ads than the value of an ad to the
1432
+ | advertisers.
1433
+ | A deeper story can be told by looking seperately at small versus large markets.
1434
+ | As mentioned in the previous section, radio stations have considerable control over
1435
+ | prices in small markets, and no control in the large markets. Motivated by this fact,
1436
+ | I present counterfactuals for markets with less than 0.5 population and more than
1437
+ | 2m population. In smaller markets (see Table 2.9), stations contract advertising to
1438
+ | exercise market power on advertisers. They supply more than 10,000 minutes less of
1439
+ | advertising. That translates into a 7.3pdm decrease in ad exposure, which increases
1440
+ | consumer surplus by 11.6pdm. However, prices rise by 6.4%, and cause a $230m
1441
+ | loss in advertiser surplus. On the other hand in large markets (see Table 2.10) firms
1442
+ | supply more than 2,000 extra minutes of advertising, which lowers consumer surplus
1443
+ | by almost 2pdm. On balance, this does not affect advertiser surplus. I conclude that
1444
+ | listeners gained form the Telecom Act only in small markets.
1445
+ blank |
1446
+ |
1447
+ title | 2.7.2 Effects of product variety and market power
1448
+ text | Berry and Waldfogel (2001) suggest that the negative effects of ownership consolida-
1449
+ | tion on listeners might be mitigated by format switching. They find that post-merger
1450
+ | repositioning results in spatial competition leading to more variety, which they as-
1451
+ | sume is beneficial for the listeners 4 . To quantify this effect, I compare surpluses
1452
+ | computed imposing 1996 ownership and formats with surpluses computed imposing
1453
+ | actual ownership and formats without ad quantity adjustments. That is, I fix ad
1454
+ | quantities computed with 1996 ownership and formats. The results of this experi-
1455
+ | ment are presented in the first row of Table 2.8. It turns out that if I do not account
1456
+ | for quantity changes, the assertion of Berry and Waldfogel (2001) is true. In this
1457
+ meta | 4
1458
+ text | Similar results obtained using direct analysis of station playlists can be found in Sweeting (2008).
1459
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 32
1460
+ blank |
1461
+ |
1462
+ |
1463
+ text | case, listeners have a 1.3% larger surplus (about 6.6pdm) after consolidation and for-
1464
+ | mat switching. Listener surplus grows because of two factors: increased variety and
1465
+ | decreased advertising exposure. The latter decreased even though I keep number of
1466
+ | ad minutes fixed. However, in the real world, repositioning changes firms’ incentives
1467
+ | to set ad quantity, because it softens competition in the advertising market. The im-
1468
+ | pact of quantity readjustments is presented in the middle row of Table 2.8. It turns
1469
+ | out that both listeners and advertisers are worse off due to quantity adjustments.
1470
+ | Listeners lose 1.9pdm and advetisers lose additional $150m in surplus.
1471
+ blank |
1472
+ |
1473
+ title | 2.8 Robustness analysis
1474
+ text | This section examines the robustness of my advertising model to different assumptions
1475
+ | about competition among station formats. This step is motivated by the fact that
1476
+ | the data concerning advertiser deals is incomplete. I deal with the incompleteness by
1477
+ | proposing a stilyzed decision model for advertisers that uses publicly available data
1478
+ | to predict substitution patterns between formats. These patterns directly detemine
1479
+ | the market power of stations over advertsers, and can potentially alter the results of
1480
+ | counterfactual experiments.
1481
+ | To investigate the robustness of the results, I reestimated the model under two
1482
+ | alternative assumptions. The first scenario represents the extreme situation in which
1483
+ | formats compete only between themselves. In particular, suppose that advertiser
1484
+ | types get utility from only one particular format. In this case, equation (2.6) has
1485
+ | ωf f = 1 and ωf f 0 = 0 if f 6= f 0 . The second scenario represents another extreme in
1486
+ | which formats are perfect substitutes, i.e., there is only one type of advertiser who
1487
+ | values all formats in the same way. Formally this means that ωf f 0 = 1/8, because
1488
+ | there are 8 possible formats. The estimated model is in a sense in-between the these
1489
+ | extreme alternatives, because it assumes that formats are imperfect substitutes.
1490
+ | Estimates of the inverse demand advertising slopes are presented in Table 2.11.
1491
+ | The estimates show that the baseline model lies between the two extremes. When we
1492
+ | assume oligopoly within a format, the estimated slope parameter θ2L is smaller than
1493
+ | the one in the baseline model. On the other hand in the perfect substitutes model,
1494
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 33
1495
+ blank |
1496
+ |
1497
+ text | Market population less than .5m between .5m and 1.5m more than 1.5m
1498
+ | Baseline model 1.34 (0.046) 0.35 (0.026) 0.00 (0.008)
1499
+ | Oligopoly within format 1.07 (0.036) 0.28 (0.061) 0.02 (0.009)
1500
+ | Perfect substitutes 1.44 (0.035) 0.32 (0.030) 0.01 (0.009)
1501
+ blank |
1502
+ text | Table 2.11: Slope of the inverse demand for ads θ2A , by market size
1503
+ | Consumer Advertiser Mean price
1504
+ | Average ad load Advertising minutes
1505
+ | surplus surplus index
1506
+ | 4.7pdm -4.8pdm -304.4m -12,329min
1507
+ | Baseline model +2.67%
1508
+ | +0.9% -9.5% -31.4% -7.3%
1509
+ | 4.4pdm -4.5pdm -253.4m -9,056min
1510
+ | Oligopoly within format +1.12%
1511
+ | +0.8% -9.0% -31.3% -5.6%
1512
+ | 4.9pdm -5.3pdm -314.7m -16,648min
1513
+ | Perfect substitutes +2.57%
1514
+ | +0.9% -10.3% -32.7% -9.0%
1515
+ blank |
1516
+ text | Table 2.12: Robustness of counterfactuals
1517
+ blank |
1518
+ text | the estimated slope tends to be higher. Despite the fact that there are statistical
1519
+ | differences between the different models, the main qualitative assertion, that stations
1520
+ | have more power in smaller markets, still holds. In order to assess the economic impli-
1521
+ | cation of those differences, I recomputed the estimated profit margin under different
1522
+ | models. It turns out that the model with format oligopoly predicts on average a 2.4%
1523
+ | higher profit margins than the baseline model. Conversely the model with perfect
1524
+ | substitutes predicts 2.1% lower profit margin.
1525
+ | To draw final conclusions about the strength of the assumption about weights, I
1526
+ | recomputed the main counterfactual using the alternative models. The results are
1527
+ | presented in Table 2.12. The baseline again lies between the new counterfactuals.
1528
+ | There is no qualitative change in the results. Moreover the percentage changes in
1529
+ | consumer and advertiser surplus are almost the same. Consequently, I conclude that
1530
+ | the results of the paper are not sensitive to changes in the assumption about substi-
1531
+ | tution between formats.
1532
+ blank |
1533
+ |
1534
+ title | 2.9 Conclusion
1535
+ text | In this paper I analyze mergers in two-sided markets on the example of the 1996-2006
1536
+ | consolidation wave in U.S. radio industry. The goal of this study is to describe and
1537
+ | quantify how mergers in the two-sided market differ from a differentiated product
1538
+ meta | CHAPTER 2. MERGERS IN TWO-SIDED MARKETS 34
1539
+ blank |
1540
+ |
1541
+ |
1542
+ text | oligopoly setting. I make two main contributions. First, I recognize the fact two-
1543
+ | sided markets consist of two types of consumers, who may be affected by the merger in
1544
+ | different ways. For example, if extra market power causes the radio station to increase
1545
+ | advertising, it will benefit consumers but hurt advertisers. Second, I disaggregate the
1546
+ | impact of a merger on consumers into changes in the variety of available products
1547
+ | and changes in supplied quantity of ads.
1548
+ | Radio is an important medium in the U.S., reaching about 94% of Americans
1549
+ | twelve years old or older each week. Moreover, the average consumer listens to about
1550
+ | 20h of radio per week and between 6am and 6pm more people use radio than TV
1551
+ | or print media5 . In 1996 the Telecommunication Act deregulated the industry by
1552
+ | raising local ownership caps. This deregulation caused a massive merger wave, that
1553
+ | reshaped the ownership structure, by moving from family based ownership into more
1554
+ | corporate structures. I estimate that this consolidation raised consumer surplus by
1555
+ | 1%, but lowered advertiser surplus by $300m. I find that the mergers created extra
1556
+ | variety that increased listener welfare by $1.3%. On the other hand they softened
1557
+ | competition and decreased advertiser welfare by $147m per year. Subsequent ad
1558
+ | quantity adjustments led to a 0.3% decrease in listener welfare (with the variety
1559
+ | effect it totals to the 1% increase) and an additional $153m decrease in advertiser
1560
+ | welfare (with the variety effect it totals $300m).
1561
+ blank |
1562
+ |
1563
+ |
1564
+ |
1565
+ meta | 5
1566
+ text | Source: A.Richter (2006)
1567
+ meta | Chapter 3
1568
+ blank |
1569
+ title | Estimation of cost synergies from
1570
+ | mergers without cost data:
1571
+ | Application to U.S. radio
1572
+ blank |
1573
+ title | 3.1 Preface
1574
+ text | This chapter develops a new way to estimate cost synergies from mergers without
1575
+ | using actual data on cost. The estimator uses a structural model in which companies
1576
+ | play a dynamic game with endogenous mergers and product repositioning decisions.
1577
+ | Such a formulation has several benefits over the widespread static merger analysis.
1578
+ | In particular, it corrects for sample selection of more profitable mergers and captures
1579
+ | follow-up mergers and post-merger product repositioning.
1580
+ | The framework is applied to estimate cost efficiencies after the deregulation of
1581
+ | U.S. radio in 1996. The procedure uses the data on radio station characteristics
1582
+ | and numerous acquisitions, without explicit need for cost data. It turns out that
1583
+ | between 1996 and 2006 additional ownership concentration generated $2.5b per-year
1584
+ | cost savings, which is about 10% of total industry revenue.
1585
+ blank |
1586
+ |
1587
+ |
1588
+ |
1589
+ meta | 35
1590
+ | CHAPTER 3. COST SYNERGIES FROM MERGERS 36
1591
+ blank |
1592
+ |
1593
+ |
1594
+ title | 3.2 Introduction
1595
+ text | The extent to which a potential merger generates cost efficiencies is often mentioned
1596
+ | by managers as a major motivation to merge. Moreover, potential fixed cost savings
1597
+ | generated by a merger are recognized by the Horizontal Merger Guidelines as a fac-
1598
+ | tor that can provide consumers with direct price-related as well as non-price-related
1599
+ | benefits. Thus, for antitrust purposes one should evaluate cost savings in addition
1600
+ | to measuring the decrease in competition. However, this approach is rarely used in
1601
+ | practice, because in most cases reliable cost data are unavailable. This paper pro-
1602
+ | vides a solution to this problem, by proposing a method to estimate cost synergies
1603
+ | without using any data on cost. This method requires only panel data on the own-
1604
+ | ership structure, product characteristics, and prices and quantities, information that
1605
+ | in most cases is easily accessible.
1606
+ | Evaluating the underlying causes of ownership consolidation requires a dynamic
1607
+ | model in which mergers are endogenous. However, most past empirical work analyzed
1608
+ | mergers in a static framework and treats market structure as given. Papers by Nevo
1609
+ | (2000), Pinkse and Slade (2004), Ivaldi and Verboven (2005) exogenously impose
1610
+ | changes in market structure on a static equilibrium model and calculate counterfactual
1611
+ | changes in prices and welfare. These models are very useful in addressing the short
1612
+ | run impacts of mergers but do not account for changes in market structure that
1613
+ | might happen as a result of a merger. Benkard, Bodoh-Creed, and Lazarev (2008)
1614
+ | evaluate the longer run effects of a merger on market structure, but still treat it
1615
+ | as an exogenous one-time event. Neither of these approaches allows for estimating
1616
+ | the supply side determinants of mergers, such as cost synergies. Furthermore, the
1617
+ | assumption that mergers are exogenous may create a selection bias that results in
1618
+ | overestimating the cost synergies (we might pick up other unobserved components
1619
+ | correlated with the propensity to merge). Furthermore, recent models assume away
1620
+ | follow-up mergers and post-merger repositioning of products.
1621
+ | To address these issues, I propose a dynamic model in the spirit of Gowrisankaran
1622
+ | (1999) in which mergers and product positioning are endogenous and are assumed to
1623
+ | happen sequentially. Such an approach enables me to estimate the cost efficiencies
1624
+ meta | CHAPTER 3. COST SYNERGIES FROM MERGERS 37
1625
+ blank |
1626
+ |
1627
+ |
1628
+ text | of consolidation without any data on cost. It also eliminates the shortcomings men-
1629
+ | tioned earlier, because it incorporates the dynamic processes directly into the model.
1630
+ | Moreover, endogenizing mergers allows for correction of sample selection by using a
1631
+ | procedure in the spirit of Heckman (1979), adjusted for a dynamic game environment.
1632
+ | The model is subsequently applied to analyze ownership consolidation in the U.S.
1633
+ | radio industry. The Telecommunications Act of 1996 increased local-market radio
1634
+ | station ownership caps, triggering an unprecedented merger wave that had the effect
1635
+ | of eliminating many small and independent radio owners. From 1996 to 2006, the
1636
+ | average Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) in local radio markets grew from 0.18
1637
+ | to 0.26, the average number of owners in the market dropped from 16.6 to 12.4,
1638
+ | and the average number of stations owned grew from 1.6 to 2.3. Such dramatic
1639
+ | changes to the market structure have raised concerns about anti-competitive aspects
1640
+ | of the deregulation (Leeper (1999), Drushel (1998), Klein (1997)). After estimating
1641
+ | the model using the method of Bajari, Benkard, and Levin (2004), I find that the
1642
+ | main incentives to merge in radio come from the cost side. Total cost side savings
1643
+ | amount to $2.5b per year, constituting about 10% of total industry revenue. Such
1644
+ | cost synergies are an order of magnitude higher than the anti-competetive effects of
1645
+ | these mergers identified by Jeziorski (2010). Moreover, the fact that consolidation
1646
+ | leads to substantial cost side synergies leads me to conclude that the Telecom Act
1647
+ | made radio advertising more competitive against other media, such as TV or the
1648
+ | Internet.
1649
+ | To my knowledge, Gowrisankaran (1999) is the only applied paper that uses a
1650
+ | dynamic framework to endogenize mergers. His analysis argued that merger dynamics
1651
+ | are very important. The main drawback of his analysis is that it was never fit to
1652
+ | real data. This was due in part to the complexity of his model and in part to
1653
+ | the lack of a good dataset. To solve the complexity problem, I utilize the latest
1654
+ | developments in the dynamic-games literature. These developments enable us to
1655
+ | estimate very complicated models without explicitly solving them (Bajari, Benkard,
1656
+ | and Levin (2004)). This paper also contributes to empirical literature on demand
1657
+ | and cost curve estimation (this started with Rosse (1970) and Rosse (1967)), by
1658
+ | accounting explicitly for the demand side incentives to merge. On the technical side,
1659
+ meta | CHAPTER 3. COST SYNERGIES FROM MERGERS 38
1660
+ blank |
1661
+ |
1662
+ |
1663
+ text | my model shares some similarities with Sweeting (2007). I concentrate on questions
1664
+ | about incentives to merge and the impact of consolidation on welfare, while Sweeting
1665
+ | focuses mainly on estimates of the format switching cost. My analysis also extends
1666
+ | his model by adding a model of ad quantity choices and endogenous mergers. Another
1667
+ | paper on a similar topic is O’Gorman and Smith (2008). They use a static oligopoly
1668
+ | model to estimate the cost curve in radio. They find that the fixed cost savings when
1669
+ | owning two stations is bounded between between 20% and 50% of per-station costs
1670
+ | (I estimate this number to be 20%). I supplement their estimates by accounting for
1671
+ | selection bias, follow-up mergers and post-merger repositioning as outlined above.
1672
+ | This chapter is organized as follows. Section 2 contains a flexible, structural
1673
+ | merger model that can applied to many industries. The estimation procedure is
1674
+ | discussed in Section 3. Section 4 describes the application of the framework to analyze
1675
+ | the merger wave in the U.S. radio industry. Section 5 concludes the paper.
1676
+ blank |
1677
+ |
1678
+ title | 3.3 Merger and repositioning framework
1679
+ text | This section presents the dynamic oligopoly model of an industry with differentiated
1680
+ | products in the spirit of Ericson and Pakes (1995). The industry is modeled as a
1681
+ | dynamic game and the players are companies holding portfolios of different products
1682
+ | (brands). The modeling effort emphasizes the actions of companies changing the
1683
+ | profolio of owned products, specifically rebranding and acquisitions. The model is
1684
+ | general enough to encompass a number of different industries and types of competi-
1685
+ | tion, by allowing for a large range of different single-period profit functions and cost
1686
+ | structures.
1687
+ blank |
1688
+ |
1689
+ title | 3.3.1 Industry basics
1690
+ text | The industry is composed of M different markets that operate in discrete time over
1691
+ | an infinite horizon. The payoff relevant market characteristics at time t are fully
1692
+ | characterized by a set of covariates dmt ∈ D that include demand shifters. In each
1693
+ | market m, there are up to Km operating firms and up to Jm active products. Let oj ∈
1694
+ meta | CHAPTER 3. COST SYNERGIES FROM MERGERS 39
1695
+ blank |
1696
+ |
1697
+ |
1698
+ text | Km be the owner of the product j. I assume that each product j ∈ Jm is characterized
1699
+ | by a triple stj = (fjt , ξjt , otj ). In particular, fjt ∈ F is a discrete characteristic, and
1700
+ | ξjt ∈ Ξ is a continuous characteristic of the product. The state of the industry at the
1701
+ | beginning of each period is therefore a duple (st , dt ) ∈ S × D.
1702
+ | To simplify the further exposition define Okt to be the number of products owned
1703
+ | t
1704
+ | by the firm k, and O−k to be the number of products owned by its competitors.
1705
+ blank |
1706
+ |
1707
+ title | 3.3.2 Players’ actions
1708
+ text | Firms can undertake two types of actions: product acquisitions and product repo-
1709
+ | sitioning. I assume that acquisitions take place first and the results are common
1710
+ | knowledge before the firms commence with repositioning.
1711
+ | In general, the product acquisition process can be very complicated. Firms can
1712
+ | acquire any subset of products owned by competitors, and multiple firms can bid to
1713
+ | acquire the same product. Therefore, the most general model of this process is likely to
1714
+ | be intractable both analytically and numerically. Additionally, the model of mergers
1715
+ | without additional structure is likely to generate multiple equilibria, which will sig-
1716
+ | nificantly complicate its estimation. To solve these problems, I follow Gowrisankaran
1717
+ | (1999) and I assume that the station acquisition process is sequential. Owners move
1718
+ | in a sequence specified by a function A : st 7→ i, where i is a permutation of the active
1719
+ | owners’ index {1, . . . , K}. In addition, for notational purposes, I set i(K +1) = K +1.
1720
+ | t
1721
+ | Let ωi(k) be the state of the industry observed by the k-th mover in the merger
1722
+ | t
1723
+ | process, before making acquisition decisions. ωi(1) is set to be equal to st . Addi-
1724
+ | tionally, every player observes a set of acquisition prices for all stations owned by
1725
+ | competitors
1726
+ | Pkt = {φtkj : otj 6= k}
1727
+ blank |
1728
+ text | These prices are the outcomes of a bargaining process that is only a function of the
1729
+ | t t
1730
+ | current observable state ωi(k) . This assumption holds if ωi(k) is the only payoff relevant
1731
+ | variable for both the acquirer and the acquiree and the prices are determined by a
1732
+ | Nash Bargaining Solution.
1733
+ | In addition to prices, the potential buyer observes a set of additive payoff/cost
1734
+ meta | CHAPTER 3. COST SYNERGIES FROM MERGERS 40
1735
+ blank |
1736
+ |
1737
+ |
1738
+ text | shocks from acquiring any competitor owned product φtk = {φtkj : otj 6= k} that is his
1739
+ | private information. A player’s i(k) action involves specifying which subset of stations
1740
+ | are to be acquired. I restrict attention to Markov strategies, so the acquisition policy
1741
+ | is a mapping
1742
+ | t t
1743
+ | ak : (ωi(k) , φtk , Pkt , dt ) 7→ {0, 1}O−k
1744
+ | t
1745
+ | After the decisions are made, a new ownership ωi(k+1) is determined, and it becomes
1746
+ | common knowledge. Player a(k + 1) proceeds with acquisitions, or if there are no
1747
+ | move active players, the game moves to product repositioning.
1748
+ | A product repositioning involves decisions about changing discrete characteristics
1749
+ | fjt of owned products, in exchange for paying a switching cost C(fj , fjt+1 ). It is,
1750
+ | similarly to acquisitions, a sequential process, and it is assumed that firms proceed
1751
+ | according to the same sequence i(k)1 .
1752
+ | The first mover i(1) in the repositioning process conditions his decision on the
1753
+ | t
1754
+ | state of the industry after the acquisitions, i.e., the observable state ω̃i(1) is equal
1755
+ | t
1756
+ | to ωi(K+1) . In the same way the k-th mover i(k) observers the repositionings done
1757
+ | t
1758
+ | by all the previous movers. This information is summarized in ω̃i(k) . In addition
1759
+ | t
1760
+ | to observing the state ω̃i(k) , the k-th mover observes payoff/cost shocks for all the
1761
+ | products of any potential type ψkt = {ψkjf
1762
+ | t
1763
+ | : otj = k, 1 ≥ f ≥ F }. The product
1764
+ | repositioning policy is a Markov strategy given by the mapping
1765
+ blank |
1766
+ text | t t
1767
+ | bk : (ω̃i(k) , ψkt , dt ) 7→ F Ok
1768
+ blank |
1769
+ text | t
1770
+ | When the choices of player i(k) are made a new industry state ω̃i(k+1) becomes a
1771
+ | common knowledge.
1772
+ | After repositioning the new industry state (st+1 , dt+1 ) is determined. st+1 is con-
1773
+ | t
1774
+ | structed by combining ω̃i(K+1) with the values of a new continuous product charac-
1775
+ | teristic ξ t+1 The following assumptions restrict the dynamics of ξ.
1776
+ blank |
1777
+ text | Assumption 3.3.1. ξjt evolves as an exogenous Markov process, for example
1778
+ blank |
1779
+ text | ξjt = ρξjt−1 + ζt (3.1)
1780
+ meta | 1
1781
+ text | This assumption is made for the simplicity of exposition and might be easily relaxed.
1782
+ meta | CHAPTER 3. COST SYNERGIES FROM MERGERS 41
1783
+ blank |
1784
+ |
1785
+ |
1786
+ text | where ζt is a mean zero IID random variable.
1787
+ blank |
1788
+ text | Moreover, market covariates are also assumed to be exogenous and Markov
1789
+ blank |
1790
+ text | Assumption 3.3.2. dt evolves as an exogenous Markov process.
1791
+ blank |
1792
+ text | These assumptions are made for simplicity of estimation. They could be poten-
1793
+ | tially relaxed if more data is available. For example, if ξ is a product quality, one
1794
+ | could assume that it is also a dynamic choice variable and estimate it directly from
1795
+ | the observed investment.
1796
+ | When the new industry state is (st+1 , dt+1 ) realized firms then play a static com-
1797
+ | petition game that yelds profits given by π̄k (st+1 , dt ).
1798
+ blank |
1799
+ |
1800
+ title | 3.3.3 Payoffs and equilibrium
1801
+ text | Given the realizations of (st , st+1 , P t , ψ t , φt , dt ) the per-period payoff for player k is
1802
+ | given by the equation
1803
+ | X
1804
+ | πk (st , st+1 ,P t , ψ t , φt , dt ) = π̄k (st+1 , dt ) − F (stk ) + (φtkj − Pkj
1805
+ | t
1806
+ | )+
1807
+ | j:otj 6=k,ot+1
1808
+ | j =k
1809
+ | X X h i (3.2)
1810
+ | t+1 t+1
1811
+ | + Pott+1 j + t t t
1812
+ | ψkjf t+1 − I(fj 6= fj )C(ff , fj )
1813
+ | j j
1814
+ | j:otj =k,ot+1
1815
+ | j 6=k j:ot+1
1816
+ | j =k
1817
+ blank |
1818
+ |
1819
+ text | where F (stk ) is the fixed cost of owning portfolio stk , and π̄k is a one-shot profit from
1820
+ | the portfolio.
1821
+ | Let g = (a1 , . . . , aK , b1 , . . . , bK ) be a Markov strategy profile. It can be shown that
1822
+ | this profile and an initial condition (s, d) determine the unique, controlled Markov
1823
+ | process over states, acquisition prices P , payoff shocks ψ and φ, and market covariates
1824
+ | d
1825
+ | P(g, s, d) ∈ ∆(S × P × Ψ × Φ × D × T )
1826
+ blank |
1827
+ text | where T is a time horizon, and ∆ is a set of probability measures. P is therefore a
1828
+ | discrete time stochastic process on S × P × Ψ × Φ × D. This process is also supplied
1829
+ | with a filtration, such that the strategy profile g is measurable.
1830
+ meta | CHAPTER 3. COST SYNERGIES FROM MERGERS 42
1831
+ blank |
1832
+ |
1833
+ |
1834
+ text | Each owner is maximizing the expected discounted sum of profits taking the strate-
1835
+ | gies of opponents g−k as given. The value function for player k is defined as
1836
+ blank |
1837
+ text | ∞
1838
+ | X
1839
+ | Vk (s, d|gk , g−k ) = EP(g,s,d) β t πk (st , st+1 , P t , ψ t , φt , dt ) (3.3)
1840
+ | t=0
1841
+ blank |
1842
+ |
1843
+ text | It is assumed that the markets are in a Markov Perfect Equilibrium, i.e., firms choose
1844
+ | strategy profile g∗ , such that for all k
1845
+ blank |
1846
+ text | Vk (s, d|g∗k , g∗−k ) ≥ Vk (s, d|gk , g∗−k ) ∀gk . (3.4)
1847
+ blank |
1848
+ text | For simplicity, I restrict my attention to symmetric equilibria. The next section
1849
+ | describes the estimation procedure.
1850
+ blank |
1851
+ |
1852
+ title | 3.4 Estimation
1853
+ text | Consider parameterizations of the fixed cost F (stk |θF ) and the switching cost
1854
+ | C(fjt , fjt+1 |θC ). This section outlines a procedure, based on Bajari, Benkard, and
1855
+ | Levin (2004), to obtain consistent estimators of θF and θC without using direct data
1856
+ | on cost.
1857
+ | The procedure has two stages. The fist stage infers equilibrium behavior from the
1858
+ | data on one or a set of similar industries. The second stage estimates the cost param-
1859
+ | eters for a particular industry by imposing the dynamic game equilibrium inequalities
1860
+ | 3.4. The following subsection describes the data needed for this procedure to work.
1861
+ blank |
1862
+ |
1863
+ title | 3.4.1 Data
1864
+ text | Consider an industry, or a set of similar industries, operating in M markets over the
1865
+ | discrete time span T . Data is given by the set X = {xtm : 1 ≤ m ≤ M, 1 ≤ t ≤ T }.
1866
+ | Each point in the data xtm describes the state of the industry at the beginning of
1867
+ | the period stm = (f tm , ξ tm , otm ), market covariates/demand shifters dtm , and a set of
1868
+ | transaction prices P mt . The data does not have to contain any direct information on
1869
+ meta | CHAPTER 3. COST SYNERGIES FROM MERGERS 43
1870
+ blank |
1871
+ |
1872
+ |
1873
+ text | the cost. This is convenient since most of the data on cost suffers from accounting
1874
+ | issues. Therefore direct cost estimates from the data might be unreliable.
1875
+ | To facilitate the inference process a standard assumption about the data gen-
1876
+ | erating process is made: that it is generated by a single MPE strategy profile g∗ .
1877
+ | Crucially, the dataset needs to contain a reasonable amount of within market acqui-
1878
+ | sitions and repositioning to allows it to identify equilibrium strategies. Sometimes it
1879
+ | is possible to obtain such datasets within one industry (see U.S. radio in the appli-
1880
+ | cation), however for most industries such datasets are unavailable. In this case, it is
1881
+ | possible to pool similar industries to construct one dataset. To make this work one
1882
+ | needs a slightly stronger assumption that equilibrium behavior is the same across the
1883
+ | pooled industries.
1884
+ | The transaction prices are helpful but not necessary to identify the cost parame-
1885
+ | ters. Estimation is possible without them but it requires more assumptions about the
1886
+ | bargaining process during the acquisition, as well as much more computing power.
1887
+ | The extra steps needed to proceed without the prices are mentioned in Appendix B.1.
1888
+ | In order to simplify the exposition all state variables are assumed to be observed.
1889
+ | However, the procedure also applies to problems in which some payoff relevant in-
1890
+ | formation is unobserved to the econometrician. In many cases one can infer the
1891
+ | unobserved state variable from a static estimation of the one-shot profit function π̄.
1892
+ | One example of such a case is Berry, Levinsohn, and Pakes (1995) estimator, which
1893
+ | uses differences of static market shares to identify unobserved product quality. More-
1894
+ | over, there are numerous ways to proceed in case one cannot directly infer all the
1895
+ | latent state variables. For example, one could supply the procedure from this chapter
1896
+ | with an EM algorithm proposed by Arcidiacono and Miller (2010).
1897
+ blank |
1898
+ |
1899
+ title | 3.4.2 Policy estimation
1900
+ text | For any strategy profile
1901
+ | g = (a1 , . . . , aK , b1 , . . . , bK )
1902
+ blank |
1903
+ text | let ProbM R
1904
+ | k (ak |ωk , dk ), and Probk (bk |ω̃k , dk ), be the probabilities of taking acquisition
1905
+ | and repositioning actions. The former is a probability measure on {0, 1}O−k , and the
1906
+ meta | CHAPTER 3. COST SYNERGIES FROM MERGERS 44
1907
+ blank |
1908
+ |
1909
+ |
1910
+ text | latter on {1, . . . , F }Ok . They are constructed by integrating out unobservable payoff
1911
+ | shocks φ and ψ. The goal of this subsection is to provide a procedure that allows us
1912
+ | to obtain the estimates of these probability measures. This procedure leverages on
1913
+ | the sequentiality assumptions made in the previous section.
1914
+ | The first step of the procedure is constructing an auxiliary dataset using a sequen-
1915
+ | tial structure of the acquisition and repositioning process. For each t, the predefined
1916
+ | sequence of player moves i = I(st ) specifies a mapping
1917
+ blank |
1918
+ text | (st , st+1 ) 7→ (ωi(1) , . . . , ωi(K) , ω̃i(1) , . . . ω̃i(K) )
1919
+ blank |
1920
+ text | This mapping is used to construct 3 sets. The first set describes the acquisition
1921
+ | dynamics
1922
+ blank |
1923
+ text | Y1 = {(ωktm , dtm , atm
1924
+ | k ) : 1 ≤ k ≤ K, 1 ≤ m ≤ M, 1 ≤ t ≤ T }
1925
+ blank |
1926
+ |
1927
+ text | where atm
1928
+ | k is a vector of zeros and ones that indicates acquisition decisions for player
1929
+ | k. The second set describes acquisition prices
1930
+ blank |
1931
+ text | Y2 = {(ωktm , dtm , Pktm ) : 1 ≤ k ≤ K, 1 ≤ m ≤ M, 1 ≤ t ≤ T }
1932
+ blank |
1933
+ text | where Pktm is a vector of prices for all acquisitions of player k. The last set describes
1934
+ | the repositioning
1935
+ blank |
1936
+ text | Y3 = {(ω̃ktm , dtm , Fkmt ) : 1 ≤ k ≤ K, 1 ≤ m ≤ M, 1 ≤ t ≤ T }
1937
+ blank |
1938
+ text | where Fkmt is a vector of chosen characteristics for products owned by firm k.
1939
+ | Set Y1 is used to estimate the acquisition probability distribution ProbM
1940
+ | k as a
1941
+ | function of (ω, d). In a perfect world, one would like to employ a form of non-
1942
+ | parametric multi-dimensional discrete choice estimator. However, in practice, the
1943
+ | researcher is likely to face two problems: the large dimensionality of covariates (ω, d)
1944
+ | and the large dimensionality of the ProbM
1945
+ | k support (due to a big number of active
1946
+ | products/companies that can be acquired).
1947
+ meta | CHAPTER 3. COST SYNERGIES FROM MERGERS 45
1948
+ blank |
1949
+ |
1950
+ |
1951
+ text | The solution to the first problem is to employ a flexible parametric form
1952
+ blank |
1953
+ text | M
1954
+ | [ k (ak |ωk , dk , θM )
1955
+ | Prob
1956
+ blank |
1957
+ text | that exhausts most of the information in the data. The asymptotics of such an
1958
+ | estimator are similar to the non-parametric estimators in which the dimensionality
1959
+ | of pseudo-parameters θM grow as the dataset becomes large.
1960
+ | The second problem is more severe and in most cases cannot be solved without
1961
+ | additional assumptions. The following examples suggest different possible approaches.
1962
+ blank |
1963
+ text | Example 3.4.1 (One acquisition per period). If the acquisitions in the data tend to
1964
+ | be rare, one could potentially assume that only one acquisition per owner is allowed
1965
+ | each period. This reduces the decision space to only one dimension and enables direct
1966
+ | application of any discrete choice model (for example logit or probit) on the data set
1967
+ | Y1 .
1968
+ blank |
1969
+ text | The second example suggests how to deal with multiple acquisitions
1970
+ blank |
1971
+ text | Example 3.4.2 (Independent acqusitions). In the case where the acquisition deci-
1972
+ | sions are uncorrelated conditional on ωk and dk one could employ a discrete choice
1973
+ | regression directly on Y1 , fixing ωktm for all decisions in ãtm
1974
+ | k .
1975
+ blank |
1976
+ |
1977
+ text | The next solution makes more assumptions about the structure of the acquisition
1978
+ | decision making within the firm.
1979
+ blank |
1980
+ text | Example 3.4.3 (Sequential acqusitions). Suppose that the acquisition decisions are
1981
+ | made in a sequence, i.e., after observing ψj for a particular product, the firm decides
1982
+ | about its acquisition without looking at the payoff shocks ψ for other stations. In
1983
+ | this case one could further expand dataset Y1 to incorporate the sequence of decisions
1984
+ | within the firm. Because of the additive structure of payoffs and the fact that ψj are
1985
+ | IID, one could consistently estimate ProbM
1986
+ | k by using a discrete choice estimator on
1987
+ | the extended dataset.
1988
+ blank |
1989
+ text | If one were to observe the acquisition prices one could estimate the pricing function
1990
+ | P (ωkst ) directly from the dataset Y2 . This could be achieved by employing the flexible
1991
+ meta | CHAPTER 3. COST SYNERGIES FROM MERGERS 46
1992
+ blank |
1993
+ |
1994
+ |
1995
+ text | parametric interpolation2 .
1996
+ | When estimating the repositioning probabilities ProbR
1997
+ | k one faces similar problems,
1998
+ | but additionally one has to deal with multinomial vs. binomial choice. The three
1999
+ | examples of solutions to that problem presented previously also apply here.
2000
+ | Additionally, one could endogenize the continuous characteristic ξ and estimate it
2001
+ | as a function of the state space using the methods presented in Bajari, Benkard, and
2002
+ | Levin (2004). Depending on the interpretation of ξ, this might involve an additional
2003
+ | model. In this paper however, ξ t as well as dt are treated as exogenous and Markov.
2004
+ | The transition in this case can be estimated as a flexible parametric auto-regressive
2005
+ | process.
2006
+ | In the next subsection I describe a second stage of the cost function estimator
2007
+ | that uses the estimators of equilibrium policy and the transition of ξ and dt obtained
2008
+ | in the first step above.
2009
+ blank |
2010
+ |
2011
+ title | 3.4.3 Minimum distance estimator
2012
+ text | For the second stage the parameters of the fixed cost θF and repositioning cost θR are
2013
+ | estimated using a minimum distance estimator. The estimator is constructed using
2014
+ | the MPE inequalities (3.4). The remainder of this section describes how I obtain
2015
+ | estimates of the value functions in those inequalities.
2016
+ | The value function Vk (defined on the equation (3.3)) can be separated into four
2017
+ | parts.
2018
+ | Vkt = Atk + θφ Bkt + θψ Ckt + Dkt
2019
+ blank |
2020
+ text | where ∞
2021
+ | X X X
2022
+ | Atk =E β r−t π̄k (st , dt ) + Porr+1 j − r
2023
+ | Pkj
2024
+ | j
2025
+ | r=t j:orj =k,or+1 6=k j:orj 6=k,or+1 =k
2026
+ | j j
2027
+ blank |
2028
+ meta | 2
2029
+ text | Sometimes the dataset on prices is sparse, i.e., one does not observe prices for every deal. In
2030
+ | this case more simplifying assumptions about the pricing process are needed.
2031
+ meta | CHAPTER 3. COST SYNERGIES FROM MERGERS 47
2032
+ blank |
2033
+ |
2034
+ |
2035
+ text | is the expected stream of advertising revenues,
2036
+ | ∞
2037
+ | X X
2038
+ | Bkt =E β r−t φrkj
2039
+ | r=t j:orj 6=k,or+1 =k
2040
+ | j
2041
+ blank |
2042
+ |
2043
+ |
2044
+ text | is the expected stream of acquisition payoff/cost shocks,
2045
+ blank |
2046
+ text | ∞
2047
+ | X X
2048
+ | Ckt = E β r−t t
2049
+ | ψkjf r+1
2050
+ | j
2051
+ | r=t j:or+1 =k
2052
+ | j
2053
+ blank |
2054
+ |
2055
+ |
2056
+ text | is the expected stream of repositioning payoff/cost shocks, and
2057
+ |  
2058
+ | ∞
2059
+ | X X
2060
+ | Dkt = E β r−t F (srk |θF ) + 1(fjr+1 6= fjr )C(fjr , fjr+1 |θC )
2061
+ |  
2062
+ | r=t j:or+1 =k
2063
+ | j
2064
+ blank |
2065
+ |
2066
+ |
2067
+ text | is the expected stream of fixed costs and repositioning costs. The extra parameters
2068
+ | θφ and θψ are needed because the first stage estimation requires normalization of the
2069
+ | variances of φ and ψ.
2070
+ | Accounting for Bkt in the simulation of profits from a merger takes care of selec-
2071
+ | tion on unobservables, as apposed to the usual static approach to mergers. Given
2072
+ | the merger decision atm tm tm
2073
+ | jk , the contribution of unobserved profits is θφ E[φjk |ajk ]. Be-
2074
+ | cause a company observes the payoff shock before making an acquisition, the merg-
2075
+ | ers that occur are selected for high value of φtm
2076
+ | jk When φ has zero mean, it is the
2077
+ | case that E[φtm tm
2078
+ | jk |ajk = 1] > 0. Failing to account for that (i.e. assuming that
2079
+ | E[φtm tm tm
2080
+ | jk |ajk = 1] = E[φjk ] = 0) would cause underestimation of profits from mergers
2081
+ | and overestimation of fixed cost synergies 3 . The same point can be made about the
2082
+ | selection on unobservables when repositioning products and inclusion of Ckt .
2083
+ | Note that only the last part of Dkt depends on the parameters of interest θF and θC
2084
+ | and the value function is linear θφ and θψ . Therefore, to compute the value function
2085
+ meta | 3
2086
+ text | When using any of the dynamic likelihood estimators proposed in the previous subsection and
2087
+ | assuming that φ is a difference of two independent Type I extreme value random variables, E[φ|a = 1]
2088
+ | can be reduced to − log(p) − 1−p p log(1 − p), where p is a probability of acquisition.
2089
+ meta | CHAPTER 3. COST SYNERGIES FROM MERGERS 48
2090
+ blank |
2091
+ |
2092
+ |
2093
+ text | for different parameter values one does not need to re-simulate the industry path
2094
+ | (st , dt ); moreover, one does not need to recompute any of Atk , Bkt , Ckt 4 . This saves
2095
+ | a large amount of processing power and makes the estimator feasible using today’s
2096
+ | computers.
2097
+ | Following the inequality (3.4), let Vkt be an equilibrium value function for player
2098
+ | k, Vk (·|g∗k , g∗−k ). Additionally, define a suboptimal value function Ṽkt to be Vk (·|gk , g∗k )
2099
+ | for some off-equilibrium strategy gk . In equilibrium, I know that max{Ṽtk −Vkt , 0} = 0
2100
+ | for the true values of θM and θR . Thus, I define a minimum distance estimator
2101
+ blank |
2102
+ text | 1 X 1
2103
+ | (θ̂M , θ̂R ) = argmin max{Ṽktm − Vktm , 0}
2104
+ | K × T × M k,t,m Atm
2105
+ | k
2106
+ blank |
2107
+ |
2108
+ text | According to the results in Bajari, Benkard, and Levin (2004) this estimator is con-
2109
+ | sistent and asymptotically normal. This finishes the description of the estimator. An
2110
+ | example of its application is contained in the next section.
2111
+ blank |
2112
+ |
2113
+ title | 3.5 Application
2114
+ text | In this section, I describe how to use above framework to estimate merger synergies
2115
+ | from ownership consolidation in the U.S. radio industry. In the next subsection I give
2116
+ | a brief review of the industry. The second subsection presents the tailored version of
2117
+ | the estimation algorithm. The last subsection presents and discusses the results.
2118
+ blank |
2119
+ |
2120
+ title | 3.5.1 Industry and data description
2121
+ text | Radio is an important medium in the U.S., reaching about 94% of Americans twelve
2122
+ | years old or older each week. Moreover, the average consumer listens to about 20
2123
+ | hours of radio per week and between 6am and 6pm more people use radio than TV
2124
+ | or print media5 . There are about 13,000 commercial radio stations that broadcast
2125
+ | in about 350 local markets nationwide. Before 1996, this industry had ownership
2126
+ meta | 4
2127
+ text | In most cases Atk is the hardest to compute because computing π̄ may involve solving a one-shot
2128
+ | Nash equilibrium price or a quantity setting game.
2129
+ meta | 5
2130
+ text | Source: A.Richter (2006)
2131
+ meta | CHAPTER 3. COST SYNERGIES FROM MERGERS 49
2132
+ blank |
2133
+ |
2134
+ text | # of active stations Old ownership cap New cap
2135
+ | 45+ 4 8
2136
+ | 30-44 4 7
2137
+ | 15-29 4 6
2138
+ | 0-14 3 5
2139
+ | Table 3.1: Change in the local ownership caps introduced by the 1996 Telecom Act.
2140
+ blank |
2141
+ |
2142
+ text | limitations both nationally and locally, preventing big corporations from entering
2143
+ | the market and thereby sustaining a large degree of family based ownership. This
2144
+ | situation changed with the Telecom Act of 1996 which, among other things, raised
2145
+ | the ownership caps in the local markets (see Table 3.1).
2146
+ | This triggered an unprecedented merger and product repositioning wave that com-
2147
+ | pletely reshaped the industry. Figure 3.1 contains the average percentage of stations
2148
+ | that switched owners and that switched formats. Between 1996 and 2000 more than
2149
+ | 10% of stations switched owners annually. After 2000 the number dropped to less
2150
+ | than 4%. Greater ownership concentration in the 1996-2000 period was also associ-
2151
+ | ated with more format switching. The percentage of stations that switched formats
2152
+ | peaked in 1998 and 2001 at 13%. In effect, the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) in
2153
+ | the listenership market grew from 0.18 in 1996 to about 0.3 in 2006.
2154
+ | The impact of this consolidation on consumer surplus has been studied before
2155
+ | using a static demand and supply approach. For example Jeziorski (2010) (Chapter
2156
+ | 2 of this thesis), finds that consolidation of ownership in this industry was harmful
2157
+ | to advertisers, causing $300m loss in advertiser surplus, but beneficial to listeners,
2158
+ | raising the welfare by 1%.
2159
+ | In order to analyze the supply side effects of this consolidation, I compiled a
2160
+ | dataset 6 . on stations in the 88 markets studied by Jeziorski (2010). The data
2161
+ | contains ownership for each station oj , and station format fj . It uses the estimates of
2162
+ | station quality ξj , contained in Jeziorski (2010). I also observe each acquisition made
2163
+ | in this market and the average acquisition price.
2164
+ meta | 6
2165
+ text | Data is constructed using the software provided by BIA Financial Network Inc. and Media
2166
+ | Market Guides by SQAD
2167
+ meta | CHAPTER 3. COST SYNERGIES FROM MERGERS 50
2168
+ blank |
2169
+ |
2170
+ |
2171
+ |
2172
+ text | Figure 3.1: Dynamics of station acquisition and format switching
2173
+ blank |
2174
+ title | 3.5.2 Static profits
2175
+ text | The static profit function is taken directly from Jeziorski (2010). Radio station owners
2176
+ | draw their revenue from selling advertising and each advertising slot is priced on a
2177
+ | per listener basis. The total profit of the owner k is equal to
2178
+ | X
2179
+ | π̄k (s, d) = rj (q ∗ , s, d)pj (q ∗ , s, d)qj∗
2180
+ | j:oj =k
2181
+ blank |
2182
+ |
2183
+ text | where q ∗ are the equilibrium advertising quantities chosen in the static oligopoly
2184
+ | game, rj is the number of listeners and pj is the price per listener. In this paper, I
2185
+ | treat the estimates of this profit function as given; however, I do correct the standard
2186
+ | errors of the dynamic estimates by accounting for the noise introduced by estimating
2187
+ | profit function.
2188
+ | The only difference between the baseline model in Jeziorski (2010) and the profit
2189
+ | function used in this chapter is that the marginal cost of production is set to zero and
2190
+ | format substitution matrix Ω is assumed to be diagonal. I made these assumptions
2191
+ meta | CHAPTER 3. COST SYNERGIES FROM MERGERS 51
2192
+ blank |
2193
+ |
2194
+ |
2195
+ text | for computational reasons.
2196
+ blank |
2197
+ |
2198
+ title | 3.5.3 Estimation details
2199
+ text | The estimation is a direct application of the framework desribed in subsection 3.4.
2200
+ | The model endogenizes acquisition decisions and format switching decisions. The
2201
+ | dynamics in an unobserved radio station quality ξ is assumed to be exogenous.
2202
+ | The first piece of the model that needs to be specified is the function I(st , dt ),
2203
+ | that prescribes the sequence of moves firms make in the merger and repositioning
2204
+ | process. Following Gowrisankaran (1999), I assume that firms with the biggest total
2205
+ | market shares move first. This is motivated by the fact that the bigger players in the
2206
+ | market might a have first-mover advantage over smaller players. The acquisition price
2207
+ | is assumed to be constant within market and equal to the observed mean acquisition
2208
+ | price.
2209
+ | To estimate the merger probability I use the method outlined in the Example
2210
+ | 3.4.3. Each owner considers, one at a time, stations to acquire, starting from the
2211
+ | one with the highest quality measure ξj , and moving down according to ξj 7 . A flow
2212
+ | chart of the merger process is presented in the Appendix B.2. Such structure enables
2213
+ | expanding the data structure on acquisitions within the firm
2214
+ blank |
2215
+ text | Ot
2216
+ | (ωkt , atk ) 7→ (ωjk
2217
+ | t
2218
+ | , atjk )j=1
2219
+ | −k
2220
+ blank |
2221
+ |
2222
+ |
2223
+ |
2224
+ text | t
2225
+ | where O−k is the number of stations owned by competitors. If we assume that ψ is a
2226
+ | difference of two extreme value distributions and is also revealed in a sequence, one
2227
+ | can consistently estimate a probability of merger ProbM
2228
+ | k , by running a regular logit
2229
+ | regression on this extended dataset.
2230
+ | The covariates in the logit regression should reflect the information about the state
2231
+ | space contained in the data. In a perfect world one would use a very flexible index
2232
+ | function of the state space variables. However, because of high dimensionality of
2233
+ | the state space, such an approach requires too many degrees of freedom, and quickly
2234
+ meta | 7
2235
+ text | Choice of ξj as an ordering characteristic is motivated by the fact that it is a vertical measure
2236
+ | of profitability.
2237
+ meta | CHAPTER 3. COST SYNERGIES FROM MERGERS 52
2238
+ blank |
2239
+ |
2240
+ |
2241
+ text | exhausts all the information available in the data. To overcome this problem, I use
2242
+ | a linear index function of several statistics about the state space computed from the
2243
+ | data 8 . The full set of covariates can be found in Table B.1 in Appendix B.3.
2244
+ | A similar strategy can be employed to estimate the format switching process. The
2245
+ | flow chart describing this process is contained in Appendix B.2. Assuming that firms
2246
+ | switch formats sequentially dictates the following dataset expansion
2247
+ blank |
2248
+ text | Ot
2249
+ | t
2250
+ | (ωkt , atk ) 7→ (ωjk , atjk )j=1
2251
+ | −k
2252
+ blank |
2253
+ |
2254
+ |
2255
+ |
2256
+ text | Using this auxiliary dataset one can apply a multinomial logit model to estimate
2257
+ | the format switching probabilities ProbR
2258
+ | k . The restriction on the index function also
2259
+ | applies in this case, so I use only a limited set of covariates (given in Table B.2 in
2260
+ | Appendix B.3).
2261
+ | In the second stage of the estimation, I parametrize the fixed cost function
2262
+ blank |
2263
+ text | F (stm tm
2264
+ | k ) = θC1 × POPm × nk θC2 (3.5)
2265
+ blank |
2266
+ text | where POPm is a population of the market m and nkt is the number of stations
2267
+ | owned by player k at time t. Parameter θC2 dictates the amount of cost synergies
2268
+ | from owning multiple stations. I also assume a constant format switching cost that
2269
+ | is proportional to the population. Those assumptions are motivated by the fact that
2270
+ | Jeziorski (2010) finds that most of the variation in marginal cost of radio operations
2271
+ | between can be explained by the variation in total population.
2272
+ | In the second stage, I simulate the value function only for the owner with the
2273
+ | biggest market share at each data point (stm , dtm ). These simulations are done ac-
2274
+ | cording to the Algorithms 2 and 3. The suboptimal value function Ṽk is obtained
2275
+ | by multiplying the merger and format switching probability by a uniform [.95, 1.05]
2276
+ | random variable. When choosing the size of the perturbations one faces a bias and
2277
+ | variance trade-off. When the size is too small the estimator start picking up the
2278
+ | noise from the simulations instead of the sub-optimality of the strategy, decreasing
2279
+ meta | 8
2280
+ text | a similar approach can be found in Sweeting (2007), Ryan (2005), Ryan and Tucker (2006), and
2281
+ | Ellickson and Arie (2005).
2282
+ meta | CHAPTER 3. COST SYNERGIES FROM MERGERS 53
2283
+ blank |
2284
+ |
2285
+ |
2286
+ text | the efficiency of the estimator. When the size is chosen to be too big, the bounds of
2287
+ | the estimator become very large creating potential bias. The chosen perturbation is
2288
+ | a compromise between those two factors.
2289
+ blank |
2290
+ |
2291
+ title | 3.5.4 Results
2292
+ text | This subsection describes the results of the estimation. The exposition is divided into
2293
+ | two parts. First, I present the policy function estimates. Then, I report the main
2294
+ | results on fixed cost and switching cost synergies.
2295
+ blank |
2296
+ title | First stage: Policy function
2297
+ blank |
2298
+ text | Tables B.3 and B.4 report coefficients from a purchase strategy probit approxima-
2299
+ | tion. They reveal that owners with larger market shares are more likely to purchase
2300
+ | new stations and are less likely to sell. Also, there are synergies when purchasing
2301
+ | multiple stations. The coefficient on the first purchase dummy PUR0 is negative while
2302
+ | coefficients on dummies for multiple purchases are positive. This indicates that it
2303
+ | is easier to negotiate the purchase of many stations, or even an entire company at
2304
+ | once, than a single station. The number of owned stations in the format (the FORMAT
2305
+ | variable in the table) has a negative influence on purchase decisions. This is evidence
2306
+ | for diversification. The coefficient of station quality is positive which suggests that
2307
+ | stations with higher quality are purchased more often.
2308
+ | Table B.5 presents the influence on future format of the following covariates:
2309
+ | change of ownership dummy, AM/FM status, and previous format. The negative
2310
+ | coefficient of a Spanish format in the first row of the table suggests that when a
2311
+ | station is purchased it is less likely to switch to Spanish format. On the other hard,
2312
+ | the positive coefficient of AC tells us that change in ownership is correlated with
2313
+ | switching to the Adult Contemporary format. The second column of the table shows
2314
+ | that FM stations are likely be of Rock or CHR format, and not so likely to be of
2315
+ | News/Talk format. The remaining rows of the table describe the Markov dynamics
2316
+ | of formats. The diagonal cells have much higher numbers than the off-diagonal ones,
2317
+ | which reflects the fact that staying in the current format is much more probable than
2318
+ meta | CHAPTER 3. COST SYNERGIES FROM MERGERS 54
2319
+ blank |
2320
+ |
2321
+ |
2322
+ text | switching.
2323
+ | Table B.6 presents the relationship between the current demographic composition
2324
+ | of the market format switching decisions. In addition, Table B.7 contains similar
2325
+ | information concerning the dynamics of the demographics (the difference between
2326
+ | two consecutive periods) and format switching. One can observe many patterns that
2327
+ | suggest firms respond to the current state of population demographics as well as to the
2328
+ | dynamics of population demographics. For example, a larger current population and
2329
+ | growth of the Hispanic population is ralated to the stations switching to a Hispanic
2330
+ | format. One can observe a similar pattern for Blacks and the Urban format, as well as
2331
+ | for older people and the News/Talk format. Those patters largely reflect correlations
2332
+ | between tastes for formats and demographics described in Jeziorski (2010).
2333
+ blank |
2334
+ title | Second stage: Fixed and switching cost
2335
+ blank |
2336
+ text | The estimated parameters of the fixed cost equation (3.5) are as follows: θ̂C1 = 0.69
2337
+ | and θ̂C2 = 0.59. Table 3.2 interprets the economic significance of these parameters in
2338
+ | terms the amount of saved fixed costs per year if two stations are commonly owned
2339
+ | compared to being separate companies. Since the amount of cost synergies depends on
2340
+ | the market population, only three representative markets are presented. Los Angeles
2341
+ | is the biggest market in the sample and the cost savings in that market amount to
2342
+ | about $4.4m per-year (roughly 10% of the revenue of a big station). Knoxville is
2343
+ | representative of medium markets and has about $0.23m of such cost savings, and
2344
+ | Bismark, a small market, has about $34k of savings. Table 3.3 presents total cost
2345
+ | savings from all mergers after the Telecom Act was passed. It turns out that the
2346
+ | merger activity lowered the fixed cost of providing radio programming by almost
2347
+ | $2.5b, amounting to almost 10% of the total revenue of the industry. Compared to
2348
+ | that, the impact on advertiser surplus identified in Jeziorski (2010) is very small. This
2349
+ | leads me to conclude that the deregulation of 1996 provided substantial operational
2350
+ | efficients that outweigh negative impacts on advertiser welfare.
2351
+ | The last set of estimates concern the product repositioning costs. The estimate of
2352
+ | the cost parameter θ̂C is 2.1. The repositioning cost for each market is the population
2353
+ | of that market multiplied θ̂C . Examples of this cost are given in Table 3.4. The
2354
+ meta | CHAPTER 3. COST SYNERGIES FROM MERGERS 55
2355
+ blank |
2356
+ |
2357
+ text | Market Los Angeles Knoxville Bismarck
2358
+ | Population 13m .7m 100k
2359
+ | Savings per year $4.4m $.23m $34k
2360
+ blank |
2361
+ |
2362
+ text | Table 3.2: Savings when two stations are owned by the same firm vs. operating
2363
+ | separately
2364
+ blank |
2365
+ text | Consumer Advertiser Fixed
2366
+ | Surplus Surplus Cost
2367
+ | Impact of
2368
+ | +1% -$300m -$2.450m
2369
+ | Telecom Act
2370
+ blank |
2371
+ |
2372
+ text | Table 3.3: Total cost savings created by mergers after 1996, compared to demand
2373
+ | effects from Jeziorski (2010)
2374
+ blank |
2375
+ text | table suggests this cost is about the yearly revenue of a big station. Such a huge
2376
+ | repositioning cost can justify some of the behavior found when analyzing the merger
2377
+ | probabilities; namely, stations tend to stay away from purchasing the formats they
2378
+ | already have. If the format switching costs were low, the optimal thing to do would
2379
+ | be to purchase stations close to your portfolio to get rid of competition and rebrand
2380
+ | them to avoid cannibalization. However, if the switching costs are high, it might be
2381
+ | optimal to avoid paying them and purchase a station further away. The previous
2382
+ | subsection and Sweeting (2008) presest the evidence of the latter type of behavior,
2383
+ | reinforcing the finding of high switching cost estimates.
2384
+ blank |
2385
+ text | Market Los Angeles Knoxville Bismarck
2386
+ | Switching cost $27m $1.5m $0.2m
2387
+ blank |
2388
+ |
2389
+ text | Table 3.4: Format switching cost for chosen markets
2390
+ meta | CHAPTER 3. COST SYNERGIES FROM MERGERS 56
2391
+ blank |
2392
+ |
2393
+ |
2394
+ title | 3.6 Conclusions
2395
+ text | This paper proposed a new estimator of a production cost curve that enables the
2396
+ | identification of cost synergies from mergers. The estimation uses inequalities rep-
2397
+ | resenting an equilibrium of a dynamic game with endogenous mergers and product
2398
+ | repositioning decisions.
2399
+ | The biggest advantage of this estimator is that it enables the identification of
2400
+ | the cost curve just from merger decisions, without using cost data. Since reliable
2401
+ | cost data is very hard to obtain, the cost side analysis of mergers was very hard to
2402
+ | perform. This method is able to solve this problem, and provides a powerful tool for
2403
+ | policy makers to improve their merger assessments.
2404
+ | Since the proposed method is based on a fully dynamic framework, it additionally
2405
+ | solves many of the problems of static merger analysis. First of all, endogenizing the
2406
+ | merger decision allows for sample selection on unobservables in the estimation and
2407
+ | correcting for the fact that only the most profitable mergers are carried out. Moreover,
2408
+ | I allow for follow-up mergers and merger waves. Additionally, endogenizing product
2409
+ | characteristics enables correction for post-merger product repositioning.
2410
+ | The estimator belongs to a class of indirect estimators proposed by Hotz, Miller,
2411
+ | Sanders, and Smith (1994) and Bajari, Benkard, and Levin (2004). Therefore, it
2412
+ | shares all the benefits of those estimators, such as conceptual simplicity of imple-
2413
+ | mentation and computational feasibility, because it avoids the computation of an
2414
+ | equilibrium. However, it also shares their downsides, such as a loss in efficiency.
2415
+ | The estimator was applied to analyze the cost side benefits of a deregulation of the
2416
+ | U.S. radio industry. It turns out that the consolidation wave in that industry between
2417
+ | 1996 and 2006 provided substantial cost synergies. These amounted to about 2 billion
2418
+ | dollars per, year and constitute about 10% of industry revenue. Such benefits are an
2419
+ | order of magnitude larger than potential losses in advertiser welfare found by Jeziorski
2420
+ | (2010). This provides a significant argument for the supporters of a deregulation bill,
2421
+ | and serves as an example of how cost curve estimation can provide additional insights
2422
+ | supplementing traditional merger analysis.
2423
+ meta | Appendix A
2424
+ blank |
2425
+ title | Additional material to Chapter 2
2426
+ blank |
2427
+ title | A.1 Advertising demand: Micro foundations
2428
+ text | In this section I present a model that rationalizes inverse demand for advertising (2.5)
2429
+ | Assume that there are A types of advertisers. Each type a ∈ A targets a certain
2430
+ | demographic group(s) da . Let γ2 be a total mass of advertisers and ASa be a share of
2431
+ | advertisers of type a in market m. Advertisers are also heterogeneous in their value
2432
+ | of the ad slot in format f , and I assume that those values are distributed uniformly
2433
+ | on the interval [0, γ1f ]. An advertiser of type a gets utility only if a listener of type da
2434
+ | hears an ad. To compute the exact expected value of an advertising slot, advertisers
2435
+ | need to know the demographic composition of each station in the market. Because
2436
+ | advertisers are small, and such detailed data is not offered by Arbitron, it seems
2437
+ | unlikely that they would be able to do that. Instead, I assume that they approximate
2438
+ | those calculations using publicly available data contained in Arbitron’s Radio Today
2439
+ | publications. These publications provide nation-wide conditional probabilities rf |a
2440
+ | of a consumer of type da choosing format f conditional on listening to the radio.
2441
+ | Advertisers take these conditional probabilities as given and compute the market
2442
+ | specific probabilities of obtaining correct listeners when advertising in each format.
2443
+ | Such computations can be done by Bayes’ Rule, i.e.
2444
+ blank |
2445
+ text | rf |a LSa
2446
+ | ra|f =
2447
+ | rf
2448
+ blank |
2449
+ meta | 57
2450
+ | APPENDIX A. ADDITIONAL MATERIAL TO CHAPTER 2 58
2451
+ blank |
2452
+ |
2453
+ text | P
2454
+ | where rf = c rf |a LSa and LSa is the population share of demographic group da ,
2455
+ | which is assumed to be known to the advertiser. Having listeners’ distributions ra|f
2456
+ | and station ratings rj (available on Arbitron’s website) at hand, advertisers compute
2457
+ | the probability of successful targeting at station j to be rj ra|f , where f is a format of
2458
+ | station j.
2459
+ | Radio stations quote costs-per-point CPPaf individually for each advertiser type
2460
+ | and format. Advertisers decide if they want to purchase advertising after observing
2461
+ | the CPPs and station ratings. Because advertisers are small and likely do not have
2462
+ | much market power over radio station owners, I assume that they are price and rating
2463
+ | takers1 . Advertisers can purchase advertising from several stations at once; however,
2464
+ | I assume away any potential complementarities.
2465
+ | In equilibrium, advertisers purchase advertising as long as their expected value is
2466
+ | above price. Let qa be the amount of advertising purchased by advertisers of type a.
2467
+ | A marginal advertiser must be indifferent between purchasing advertising or not, so
2468
+ | the clearing per-listener prices are given by
2469
+ blank |  
2470
+ text | 1
2471
+ | CPPaf = γ1f ra|f 1− qa
2472
+ | γ2 ASa
2473
+ blank |
2474
+ text | Given the clearing prices CPPaf , advertisers are indifferent when choosing between
2475
+ | formats, so I assume that advertising is purchased proportionally to the target lis-
2476
+ | P
2477
+ | teners’ tastes i.e. qa = ASa f rf |a qf . If I make the simplifying assumption that
2478
+ | ASa ≈ LSa , then the arrival probability of an advertiser of type a at a station of
2479
+ | format f would be equal to ra|f . Therefore, expected per-listener price in format f is
2480
+ | given by
2481
+ | !
2482
+ | X
2483
+ | 2 1 X
2484
+ | CPPf = (ra|f ) γ1f 1 − rf 0 |a qf 0 =
2485
+ | a
2486
+ | γ2 f 0
2487
+ | ! !−1 
2488
+ | X 1 X X X
2489
+ | = γ1f (ra|f )2 1 − qf 0 (ra|f )2 (ra|f )2 rf 0 |a  .
2490
+ | a
2491
+ | γ 2
2492
+ | f0 a a
2493
+ blank |
2494
+ meta | 1
2495
+ text | This assumption is is motivated by the fact that about 75% is purchased by small local firms.
2496
+ | Such firms’ advertising decisions are unlikely to influence prices and station ratings in the short run.
2497
+ meta | APPENDIX A. ADDITIONAL MATERIAL TO CHAPTER 2 59
2498
+ blank |
2499
+ |
2500
+ |
2501
+ text | Finally, I obtain Equation (2.5)
2502
+ | !
2503
+ | X
2504
+ | A
2505
+ | pj = θ1f rj 1 − θ2A ωfmf 0 qf 0
2506
+ | f 0 ∈F
2507
+ blank |
2508
+ |
2509
+ text | 2 −1 1
2510
+ | P  P 2 A
2511
+ | by setting ωjj 0 = a (ra|f ) a (ra|f ) rf 0 |a , θ2 = γ2 and assuming that θ1 =
2512
+ | γ1f a (ra|f )2 for all f . The last assumption basically means that niche formats (with
2513
+ | P
2514
+ blank |
2515
+ text | listenership concentrated in one demographic bin) are less profitable for advertisers
2516
+ | than general interest formats.
2517
+ | The presented model is only one of a number of ways to rationalize the weighted
2518
+ | price equation (2.5) in which competition between formats is channeled though demo-
2519
+ | graphics. Other possibilities include: a local monopoly in which each advertiser type
2520
+ | draws utility only from advertising on one particular station, and a format-monopoly
2521
+ | in which each advertiser type targets only one format.
2522
+ blank |
2523
+ |
2524
+ title | A.2 Numerical considerations
2525
+ text | To solve the optimization problem (2.12), I used a version of the Gauss-Newton
2526
+ | method implemented in the commercial solver KNITRO. Using this state-of-the-art
2527
+ | solver avoids certain convergence problems that are common to many non-linear es-
2528
+ | timators.
2529
+ | The iteration step of the KNITRO solver requires computing constraints, a Jaco-
2530
+ | bian of the constraint, and an inverse of the inner product of this Jacobian (used to
2531
+ | compute the approximate Hessian of the Lagrangian). The objective function and its
2532
+ | Jacobian come essentially for free because of their simple nature.
2533
+ | To compute the constraints and their Jacobian, I employed a piece of highly opti-
2534
+ | mized parallel C code. This allows the use a fairly large dataset (about 42,000 obser-
2535
+ | vations) and many draws (500 draws from Normal and CPS per date/market) when
2536
+ | computing the constraints. When parallelizing the code, I was careful to maintain
2537
+ | independence of the draws within and between threads. To achieve this, I imple-
2538
+ | mented a version of a pseudo-random number generator (described in (L’Ecuyer and
2539
+ meta | APPENDIX A. ADDITIONAL MATERIAL TO CHAPTER 2 60
2540
+ blank |
2541
+ |
2542
+ |
2543
+ text | Andres 1997). This generator enables us to create a desired number of independent
2544
+ | pseudo-random feeds for each thread.
2545
+ | One iteration of the solver takes about two to three minutes on an 8-Core 3Ghz
2546
+ | Intel Xeon processor and uses about 4GB of memory. About 90% of this computation
2547
+ | is the inversion of a Hessian estimator within the KNITRO solver. This inversion
2548
+ | cannot be parallelized because it is done inside the solver, without the user’s control.
2549
+ meta | Appendix B
2550
+ blank |
2551
+ title | Additional material to Chapter 3
2552
+ blank |
2553
+ title | B.1 Estimation without acquisition prices
2554
+ text | r
2555
+ | In case the pricing function P̂jk cannot be estimated in the first state because of data
2556
+ | constraint, one could employ a bargaining model for infer it. Suppose one employs
2557
+ | a parametrization P̂ (ω|θP ). For an initial value of parameters θP0 one could compute
2558
+ | a surplus from acquisition of the product j by an owner k using simulated V̂kt and
2559
+ | V̂kt0 where k 0 is the current owner of product j. Then using a bargaining model
2560
+ | one could infer prices and fit a new parametrization θP1 . If repeating this procedure
2561
+ | leads to convergence, then obtain a parametrization θ̂P and value functions V̂kt that
2562
+ | are consistent with eachother. The detailed description of this procedure is given
2563
+ | in the Algorithm 1. The big dowside of this approch is that one needs resolve this
2564
+ | procedure for any set of cost parameters and cannot take advantage of linearing
2565
+ | of the value function. It makes the procedure infeasible to use for large datasets
2566
+ | because of computational burden. However, given the rapid hardware development
2567
+ | it is reasonable to think it it would be feasible in the near future.
2568
+ blank |
2569
+ |
2570
+ |
2571
+ |
2572
+ meta | 61
2573
+ | APPENDIX B. ADDITIONAL MATERIAL TO CHAPTER 3 62
2574
+ blank |
2575
+ |
2576
+ |
2577
+ text | Algorithm 1: Estimator without price data
2578
+ | Take any θP0 ;
2579
+ | Let r = 0;
2580
+ | repeat
2581
+ | Simulate the value functions V̂ r using pricing process P̂ (ω|θPr );
2582
+ | Compute surplus from any acquisition using the simulated value functions;
2583
+ | Compute acquisition prices P̂jm by applying any bargaining game;
2584
+ | Fit new parameters θPr+1 using P̂jm ;
2585
+ | until convergence of θPr ;
2586
+ blank |
2587
+ |
2588
+ title | B.2 Radio acquisition and format switching algo-
2589
+ | rithms
2590
+ text | This section of the appendix contains a detailed flows of the algorithms used to
2591
+ | simulate the value function from section 3.5.
2592
+ | Algorithm 2: Merger algorithm
2593
+ | Let ω1r = sr ;
2594
+ | foreach firm k in a sequence I(sr ) do
2595
+ | Let J−k be a set of stations not owned by k sorted by ξjr ;
2596
+ | foreach station j in J−k do
2597
+ | r
2598
+ | Set purchase price Pjk = P̄ m ;
2599
+ | M
2600
+ | Compute acquisition probability Prob[ (ω r , dt );
2601
+ | k
2602
+ | Draw a random number u from U [0, 1];
2603
+ | M
2604
+ | if u ≤ Prob
2605
+ | [ then
2606
+ | Increase Arold owner by β r−t Pjk
2607
+ | r
2608
+ | ;
2609
+ | r r−t r
2610
+ | Decrease Ak by β Pjk ;
2611
+ | Update ωkr for acqusition;
2612
+ | Increase Bkr by β r−t E[φ|acquisition];
2613
+ | end
2614
+ | end
2615
+ | r
2616
+ | Let ωk+1 = ωkr ;
2617
+ | end
2618
+ meta | APPENDIX B. ADDITIONAL MATERIAL TO CHAPTER 3 63
2619
+ blank |
2620
+ |
2621
+ |
2622
+ text | Algorithm 3: Format switching algorithm
2623
+ | Let ω̃1r = ωK+1
2624
+ | r
2625
+ | ;
2626
+ | foreach firm k in a sequence I(sr ) do
2627
+ | Let Jk be a set of stations owned by k sorted by ξjr ;
2628
+ | foreach station j in Jk do
2629
+ | R
2630
+ | [ k (ω̃ r , dr );
2631
+ | Compute repositioning probabilities Prob k
2632
+ | Simulate the future characteristic fjr+1 ;
2633
+ | Increase Ckr by β r−t E[ψ|fjr ];
2634
+ | if the fj changed then
2635
+ | Update ω̃kr ;
2636
+ | Remember the repositioning for a computation of Dkr ;
2637
+ | end
2638
+ | end
2639
+ | tm
2640
+ | Let ω̃k+1 = ω̃ktm ;
2641
+ | end
2642
+ blank |
2643
+ |
2644
+ |
2645
+ |
2646
+ title | B.3 Policy function covariates
2647
+ text | This section of the appendix contains tables of covariates used in the first stage in
2648
+ | the estimation in section 3.5.
2649
+ | Format switching strategy
2650
+ | PUR Dummy equal to 1 if station was recently purchased
2651
+ | FM AM/FM dummy, equals to 1 if considered station is FM
2652
+ | FORMAT Past format dummies
2653
+ | PORT F Number of stations owner in format F
2654
+ | PORT COMPJ F Number of stations competitor J owns in format F, competitors of
2655
+ | ranking 4 or higher are pooled
2656
+ | XI PORT F Average quality of stations owner in format F
2657
+ | XI PORT COMPJ F Average quality of stations competitor J owns in format F, competi-
2658
+ | tors of ranking 4 or higher are pooled
2659
+ | - Demographic characteristics of the market
2660
+ blank |
2661
+ text | Table B.1: Covariates for the format switching strategy multinomial logic regression.
2662
+ meta | APPENDIX B. ADDITIONAL MATERIAL TO CHAPTER 3
2663
+ text | Purchase strategy
2664
+ | OWNER1. . . OWNER4 Dummies that are equal to the ranking of the player in terms of total market share of
2665
+ | owned stations. If ranking is lower that 4 we activate the fourth dummy
2666
+ | PAST OWNER1. . . PAST OWNER4 Ranking of the previous owner of the station amongst the competitors.
2667
+ | TRIAL Describes how many stations did this player considered to purchase already this period.
2668
+ | For explanation of sequential purchase decision process look in Section 3.5.3
2669
+ | PUR0. . . PUR3 Dummies describing number of stations already purchased
2670
+ | FORMAT Number of stations owned in the format of considered station
2671
+ | FORMAT COMP1. . . FORMAT COMP4 Number of stations owned by competitors in the considered station, by ranking.
2672
+ | FORMAT COMP4 are pooled competitors with ranking of 4 or higher
2673
+ | FM AM/FM dummy, equals to 1 if considered station is FM
2674
+ | PORT F Number of stations owner in format F
2675
+ | PORT COMPJ F Number of stations competitor J owns in format F, competitors of ranking 4 or higher
2676
+ | are pooled
2677
+ | XI Average quality of stations owned in the format of considered station
2678
+ | XI COMP1. . . XI COMP4 Average quality of stations owned by competitors in the considered station, by ranking.
2679
+ | XI COMP4 are pooled competitors with ranking of 4 or higher
2680
+ | XI PORT F Average quality of stations owner in format F
2681
+ | XI PORT COMPJ F Average quality of stations competitor J owns in format F, competitors of ranking 4 or
2682
+ | higher are pooled
2683
+ | - Dummies of the format of considered station interacted with demographic characteris-
2684
+ | tics of the market
2685
+ blank |
2686
+ text | Table B.2: Covariates for the purchase strategy logic regression.
2687
+ blank |
2688
+ |
2689
+ |
2690
+ |
2691
+ meta | 64
2692
+ | APPENDIX B. ADDITIONAL MATERIAL TO CHAPTER 3 65
2693
+ blank |
2694
+ |
2695
+ |
2696
+ title | B.4 First stage estimates: Dynamic model
2697
+ blank |
2698
+ text | Top 1 Owner Top 2 Owner Top 3 Owner
2699
+ | Buyer 0.5127 0.3423 0.2608
2700
+ | Seller −0.3772 −0.2792 −0.0257
2701
+ blank |
2702
+ text | Table B.3: Station purchase policy estimates - buyer/seller dummies
2703
+ blank |
2704
+ |
2705
+ |
2706
+ text | Estimator
2707
+ | PUR0 −2.6082
2708
+ | PUR1 0.7548
2709
+ | PUR2 0.4279
2710
+ | PUR3 0.2463
2711
+ | FORMAT −0.0534
2712
+ | FORMAT COMP1 −0.0038
2713
+ | FORMAT COMP2 −0.0556
2714
+ | FORMAT COMP3 0.0728
2715
+ | FORMAT COMP4 −0.0428
2716
+ | FM 0.0151
2717
+ | STATION XI −0.1069
2718
+ | XI 0.0596
2719
+ | XI COMP1 0.0270
2720
+ | XI COMP2 0.0712
2721
+ | XI COMP3 0.0767
2722
+ | XI COMP4 −0.0117
2723
+ blank |
2724
+ text | Table B.4: Station purchase policy estimates - other variables
2725
+ meta | APPENDIX B. ADDITIONAL MATERIAL TO CHAPTER 3 66
2726
+ blank |
2727
+ |
2728
+ |
2729
+ |
2730
+ text | AC Rock CHR Urban News Country Spanish Other
2731
+ | Alt. Talk
2732
+ | PURCHASE 0.30 −0.14 0.04 −0.07 0.05 0.03 −0.23 −0.22
2733
+ | FM 1.26 1.54 1.35 1.06 −0.25 1.31 0.56 0.85
2734
+ | AC 3.70 −0.47 −0.34 −0.86 −0.43 0.37 −0.66 −0.44
2735
+ | Rock −0.27 4.41 −0.58 −0.18 −0.10 0.48 −0.32 −0.21
2736
+ | CHR −0.24 −0.42 4.38 −0.06 −0.19 0.00 −0.14 −0.35
2737
+ | Urban −0.49 0.05 −0.35 4.06 −0.17 0.48 −0.15 −0.22
2738
+ | Alt.
2739
+ | News −1.00 −0.84 −0.82 −1.29 3.89 0.25 −0.80 −0.93
2740
+ | Talk
2741
+ | Country −1.14 −1.01 −1.06 −1.35 −0.63 4.76 −0.73 −1.15
2742
+ | Spanish −1.61 −1.45 −1.30 −1.61 −1.20 −0.29 3.10 −1.42
2743
+ | Other −0.89 −1.07 −1.31 −1.27 −0.86 0.00 −1.22 3.02
2744
+ | Dark −2.18 −2.42 −2.50 −2.62 −1.61 −0.72 −1.60 −1.31
2745
+ blank |
2746
+ text | Table B.5: Format switching policy estimates - format dynamics
2747
+ blank |
2748
+ |
2749
+ |
2750
+ |
2751
+ text | AC Rock CHR Urban News Country Spanish Other
2752
+ | Alt. Talk
2753
+ | Age 12-17 0.00 −0.27 0.04 −0.50 −0.33 −0.67 −0.50 −0.32
2754
+ | Age 18-24 0.00 −0.31 −0.26 −0.69 0.31 0.00 −0.42 −0.36
2755
+ | Age 25-34 −0.54 0.00 0.02 −0.37 −0.14 −0.99 −0.06 −0.32
2756
+ | Age 35-44 −0.48 −0.00 −0.20 −0.32 −0.06 −1.17 −0.42 −0.08
2757
+ | Age 45-49 −0.46 0.00 −0.93 −0.61 0.23 −0.89 −0.81 −0.09
2758
+ | Age 50-54 −0.44 −0.41 −1.36 −0.67 0.42 −0.82 −0.62 −0.09
2759
+ | Age 55-64 0.00 −0.64 −1.49 −0.68 0.34 −0.77 −0.42 −0.16
2760
+ | Gender −0.41 −0.23 −0.43 −0.54 −0.00 −0.84 −0.34 −0.21
2761
+ | Some HS −0.38 −0.49 −0.41 −0.33 −0.27 −0.13 0.06 0.02
2762
+ | HS Grad. 0.19 0.00 −0.52 −0.32 −0.84 −0.29 −0.90 −0.19
2763
+ | Some College −0.12 −0.34 −0.72 −0.70 0.23 −0.45 −0.45 −0.03
2764
+ | Income 0-25k −0.16 −0.83 −0.32 −0.13 −0.35 −0.43 −0.52 −0.03
2765
+ | Income 25k-50k −0.06 −0.54 0.14 −0.39 −0.33 −0.34 −0.13 0.00
2766
+ | Income 50k-75k −0.07 −0.02 −0.54 −0.22 0.21 −0.39 −1.10 −0.17
2767
+ | Black −0.99 −0.58 0.00 1.25 −0.44 −1.11 −0.54 −0.26
2768
+ | Hispanic −0.55 0.19 −0.36 −0.06 −0.49 −0.20 2.42 −0.56
2769
+ blank |
2770
+ text | Table B.6: Format switching policy estimates - current demographics
2771
+ meta | APPENDIX B. ADDITIONAL MATERIAL TO CHAPTER 3 67
2772
+ blank |
2773
+ |
2774
+ |
2775
+ |
2776
+ text | AC Rock CHR Urban News Country Spanish Other
2777
+ | Alt. Talk
2778
+ | Age 12-17 0.00 0.00 0.00 6.69 −5.06 0.00 9.33 0.00
2779
+ | Age 18-24 −7.73 3.44 17.89 0.00 0.00 −12.76 0.00 6.06
2780
+ | Age 25-34 4.29 0.00 0.00 0.00 −1.35 5.23 4.32 −3.59
2781
+ | Age 35-44 2.65 0.00 5.23 1.83 −4.83 0.00 2.67 1.73
2782
+ | Age 45-49 −3.31 0.00 9.04 0.00 2.31 −3.45 −2.98 2.59
2783
+ | Age 50-54 −3.27 0.00 −2.60 −1.95 1.63 0.04 −3.37 0.00
2784
+ | Age 55-64 −4.57 −3.19 −7.50 0.00 7.73 0.00 −1.12 0.00
2785
+ | Gender 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
2786
+ | Some HS −0.03 −0.06 1.14 0.33 1.08 −0.06 −0.34 −1.09
2787
+ | HS Grad. −0.56 0.00 1.18 0.90 0.84 −0.16 −0.31 −0.47
2788
+ | Some College −0.40 −0.64 0.50 0.24 0.36 0.00 1.33 −0.89
2789
+ | Income 0-25k 0.43 0.37 0.05 0.20 0.32 0.33 −0.63 0.18
2790
+ | Income 25k-50k −0.01 0.61 −0.19 −0.49 0.18 −0.36 −1.11 −0.44
2791
+ | Income 50k-75k 0.32 0.64 0.51 −0.02 −0.01 −0.01 0.17 0.41
2792
+ | Black 4.09 −21.64 −49.49 3.51 0.00 8.71 0.00 5.16
2793
+ | Hispanic −2.86 −1.55 −3.64 0.77 −0.24 −1.65 4.84 0.00
2794
+ blank |
2795
+ text | Table B.7: Format switching policy estimates - demographic dynamics
2796
+ title | Bibliography
2797
+ blank |
2798
+ ref | Ackerberg, D. A., and M. Rysman (2005): “Unobserved Product Differentia-
2799
+ | tion in Discrete-Choice Models: Estimating Price Elasticities and Welfare Effects,”
2800
+ | RAND Journal of Economics, 36(4), 771–788.
2801
+ blank |
2802
+ ref | Arcidiacono, P., and R. Miller (2010): “CCP Estimation of Dynamic Discrete
2803
+ | Choice Models with Unobserved Heterogeneity,” Discussion paper, Duke Univer-
2804
+ | sity.
2805
+ blank |
2806
+ ref | Argentesi, E., and L. Filistrucchi (2007): “Estimating market power in a two-
2807
+ | sided market: The case of newspapers,” Journal of Applied Econometrics, 22(7),
2808
+ | 1247–1266.
2809
+ blank |
2810
+ ref | A.Richter, W. (2006): Radio: Complete Guide to the Industry. Peter Lang Pub-
2811
+ | lishing.
2812
+ blank |
2813
+ ref | Armstrong, M. (2006): “Competition in Two-Sided Markets,” The RAND Journal
2814
+ | of Economics, 37(3), 668–691.
2815
+ blank |
2816
+ ref | Bain, J. (1968): Industrial organization. John Wiley & Sons.
2817
+ blank |
2818
+ ref | Bajari, P., C. L. Benkard, and J. Levin (2004): “Estimating Dynamic Models
2819
+ | of Imperfect Competition,” NBER Working Papers 10450, National Bureau of
2820
+ | Economic Research, Inc.
2821
+ blank |
2822
+ ref | Benkard, C. L., A. Bodoh-Creed, and J. Lazarev (2008): “Simulating the
2823
+ | Dynamic Effects of Horizontal Mergers: U.S. Airlines,” Discussion paper, Stanford
2824
+ | University.
2825
+ blank |
2826
+ meta | 68
2827
+ | BIBLIOGRAPHY 69
2828
+ blank |
2829
+ |
2830
+ |
2831
+ ref | Berry, S., J. Levinsohn, and A. Pakes (1995): “Automobile Prices in Market
2832
+ | Equilibrium,” Econometrica, 63(4), 841–90.
2833
+ blank |
2834
+ ref | Berry, S. T. (1994): “Estimating Discrete-Choice Models of Product Differentia-
2835
+ | tion,” RAND Journal of Economics, 25(2), 242–262.
2836
+ blank |
2837
+ ref | Berry, S. T., and J. Waldfogel (2001): “Do Mergers Increase Product Variety?
2838
+ | Evidence From Radio Broadcasting,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(3),
2839
+ | 1009–1025.
2840
+ blank |
2841
+ ref | Brynjolfsson, E., Y. J. Hu, and M. D. Smith (2003): “Consumer Surplus in
2842
+ | the Digital Economy: Estimating the Value of Increased Product Variety at Online
2843
+ | Booksellers,” Manage. Sci., 49(11), 1580–1596.
2844
+ blank |
2845
+ ref | Bulow, J. I., J. D. Geanakoplos, and P. D. Klemperer (1985): “Multimar-
2846
+ | ket Oligopoly: Strategic Substitutes and Complements,” The Journal of Political
2847
+ | Economy, 93(3), 488–511.
2848
+ blank |
2849
+ ref | Chandra, A., and A. Collard-Wexler (2009): “Mergers in Two-Sided Markets:
2850
+ | An Application to the Canadian Newspaper Industry,” Journal of Economics &
2851
+ | Management Strategy, 18, 1045–1070.
2852
+ blank |
2853
+ ref | CRA International (2007): “Expost Merger Review: An Evaluation of Three
2854
+ | Competition Bureau Merger Assessments,” Discussion paper, CRA International.
2855
+ blank |
2856
+ ref | Deaton, A., and J. Muellbauer (1980): “An Almost Ideal Demand System,”
2857
+ | The American Economic Review, 70(3), 312–326.
2858
+ blank |
2859
+ ref | Department of Justice (1997): “Horizontal Merger Guidelines,” Discussion pa-
2860
+ | per, Department of Justice.
2861
+ blank |
2862
+ ref | Drushel, B. E. (1998): “The Telecommunications Act of 1996 and Radio Market
2863
+ | Structure,” Journal of Media Economics, 11.
2864
+ blank |
2865
+ ref | Dukes, A. (2004): “The Advertising Market in a Product Oligopoly,” Journal of
2866
+ | Industrial Economics, 52(3), 327–348.
2867
+ meta | BIBLIOGRAPHY 70
2868
+ blank |
2869
+ |
2870
+ |
2871
+ ref | Ellickson, P., and B. Arie (2005): “The Dynamics of Retail Oligopolies,” 2005
2872
+ | Meeting Papers 829, Society for Economic Dynamics.
2873
+ blank |
2874
+ ref | Ericson, R., and A. Pakes (1995): “Markov-Perfect Industry Dynamics: A Frame-
2875
+ | work for Empirical Work,” Review of Economic Studies, 62(1), 53–82.
2876
+ blank |
2877
+ ref | European Commission (2004): “Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal merg-
2878
+ | ers,” Discussion paper, European Commission.
2879
+ blank |
2880
+ ref | Evans, D. S. (2002): “The Antitrust Economics of Two-Sided Markets,” SSRN
2881
+ | eLibrary.
2882
+ blank |
2883
+ ref | Gowrisankaran, G. (1999): “A Dynamic Model of Endogenous Horizonal Merg-
2884
+ | ers,” RAND Journal of Economics, 30(1), 56–83.
2885
+ blank |
2886
+ ref | Heckman, J. J. (1979): “Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error,” Econo-
2887
+ | metrica, 47(1), 153–161.
2888
+ blank |
2889
+ ref | Hotz, V. J., R. A. Miller, S. Sanders, and J. Smith (1994): “A Simula-
2890
+ | tion Estimator for Dynamic Models of Discrete Choice,” The Review of Economic
2891
+ | Studies, 61(2), 265–289.
2892
+ blank |
2893
+ ref | Ivaldi, M., and F. Verboven (2005): “Quantifying the effects from horizontal
2894
+ | mergers in European competition policy,” International Journal of Industrial Or-
2895
+ | ganization, 23(9-10), 669–691.
2896
+ blank |
2897
+ ref | Jeziorski, P. (2010): “Impact of mergers and changes in product diversity on split
2898
+ | of surplus in two-sided markets: Case of U.S. radio industry,” Discussion paper,
2899
+ | Stanford University, Working Paper.
2900
+ blank |
2901
+ ref | Kaiser, U., and J. Wright (2006): “Price structure in two-sided markets: Evi-
2902
+ | dence from the magazine industry,” International Journal of Industrial Organiza-
2903
+ | tion, 24(1), 1 – 28.
2904
+ blank |
2905
+ ref | Kim, J., G. M. Allenby, and P. E. Rossi (2002): “Modeling Consumer Demand
2906
+ | for Variety,” Marketing Science, 21(3), 229–250.
2907
+ meta | BIBLIOGRAPHY 71
2908
+ blank |
2909
+ |
2910
+ |
2911
+ ref | Klein, J. I. (1997): “DOJ Analysis of Radio Mergers,” speech delivered in Wash-
2912
+ | ington DC,
2913
+ | http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/1055.pdf.
2914
+ blank |
2915
+ ref | L’Ecuyer, P., and T. H. Andres (1997): “A Random Number Generator Based
2916
+ | on the Combination of Four LCGs,” in Mathematics and Computers in Simulation,
2917
+ | pp. 99–107.
2918
+ blank |
2919
+ ref | Leeper, S. E. (1999): “Game of Radiopoly: An Antitrust Perspective of Consoli-
2920
+ | dation in the Radio Industry,” Fed. Comm. L.J., 52(473).
2921
+ blank |
2922
+ ref | Nevo, A. (2000): “Mergers with Differentiated Products: The Case of the Ready-
2923
+ | to-Eat Cereal Industry,” RAND Journal of Economics, 31(3), 395–421.
2924
+ blank |
2925
+ ref | O’Gorman, C., and H. Smith (2008): “Efficiency Gain from Ownership Deregula-
2926
+ | tion: Estimates for the Radio Industry,” CEPR Discussion Papers 6699, C.E.P.R.
2927
+ | Discussion Papers.
2928
+ blank |
2929
+ ref | Pinkse, J., and M. E. Slade (2004): “Mergers, brand competition, and the price
2930
+ | of a pint,” European Economic Review, 48(3), 617 – 643.
2931
+ blank |
2932
+ ref | Rochet, J.-C., and J. Tirole (2006): “Two-Sided Markets: A Progress Report,”
2933
+ | The RAND Journal of Economics, 37(3), 645–667.
2934
+ blank |
2935
+ ref | Rosse, J. N. (1967): “Daily Newspapers, Monopolistic Competition, and Economies
2936
+ | of Scale,” The American Economic Review, 57(2), 522–533.
2937
+ blank |
2938
+ ref | (1970): “Estimating Cost Function Parameters without Using Cost Data:
2939
+ | Illustrated Methodology,” Econometrica, 38(2), 256–75.
2940
+ blank |
2941
+ ref | Ryan, S. (2005): “The Costs of Environmental Regulation in a Concentrated In-
2942
+ | dustry,” Working Papers 0510, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Center for
2943
+ | Energy and Environmental Policy Research.
2944
+ blank |
2945
+ ref | Ryan, S., and C. Tucker (2006): “Heterogeneity and the Dynamics of Technology
2946
+ | Adoption,” Working Papers 06-26, NET Institute.
2947
+ meta | BIBLIOGRAPHY 72
2948
+ blank |
2949
+ |
2950
+ |
2951
+ ref | Sweeting, A. (2007): “Dynamic Product Repositioning in Differentiated Product
2952
+ | Markets: The Case of Format Switching in the Commercial Radio Industry,” NBER
2953
+ | Working Papers 13522, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
2954
+ blank |
2955
+ ref | (2008): “The Effects of Horizontal Mergers on Product Positioning: Evi-
2956
+ | dence from the Music Radio Industry,” working paper, Duke University.
2957
+ blank |